At the time this article was published
John Christopher was a member of the Science and Technology Division of the Research
Branch of the Library of Parliament.
There have been many calls over the past few
years for a change in transportation policy, or the creation of a new one. This
was not in response to a transportation revolution, but rather a result of
complaints by transportation users that the present policy has not solved
transportation problems especially in the West. In this paper the author
outlines present transportation policy, some transportation concerns and
problems, and the need for future policy changes.
Present national transportation policy had
its beginnings in the late 1950s with the establishment by the Federal
Government of the MacPherson Royal Commission to undertake, among other things,
a general investigation of freight rate problems. It also examined the role of
competition in transportation, the nature of future transportation regulations,
transportation subsidies, and inter-modal co-ordination.
The main recommendations of the Commission
centered on the philosophy of free competition. It believed that competition
was now a major factor in Canadian transportation and that as much as possible,
free competition between transport modes should be the regulating factor over
freight rates. If special cases arose then the Government could intervene to
correct the problem.
The recommendations of the Commission were
not acted upon until legislation was passed in 1967, six years after its report
was made public. These included the elimination of uneconomic rail passenger
services except where no reasonable alternative existed; the payment of
subsidies to compensate railways for losses they incurred carrying export grain
at Crowsnest Pass rates; and the rationalization of uneconomic branch rail
lines in the West. But the cornerstone of the new legislation was to be free
competition. This philosophy was legislated in the National Transportation Act
(NTA) of 1967.
The main reason for the Act was to establish
a national transportation policy for Canada, dealing with all modes of
transportation. The objective of the policy as stated in the Act declares that
an economic, efficient and adequate system making the best use of all available
modes of transportation at the lowest cost is essential to protect the
interests of users of transportation and to maintain the economic growth and
wellbeing of Canada (1966-67, C.69, s.3). The Act goes on to state that the
conditions necessary for the achievement of the objectives include regulations
that do not restrict the ability of the modes to compete freely, carriers being
compensated for providing imposed public services which are unprofitable; and
rates being charged by carriers which do not constitute an unfair disadvantage
or undue obstacle to the carriage of traffic. This was a departure from
previous transportation thinking, which had been based on tight control and
regulation of carriers. While less regulation was being espoused, the Act still
allowed for subsidies to be paid and carriers compensated for unprofitable
services they are ordered to maintain.
In addition, the Act established the
Canadian Transport Commission (CTC) to help direct and shape transportation
policy. By doing this, the CTC was given the power under Section 23 of the Act
to look into and investigate any instances of "unfair disadvantage"
or "undue obstacle" to the public interest with regard to
transportation services. It can disallow freight rate increases or compel
carriers to provide services when it is deemed in the public interest to do so.
So, while the Act favours less transportation regulation, the CTC does exercise
a degree of control over transportation services and the setting of rates.
As a result, we now have a national
transportation policy that advocates freer competition and less regulation.
with the goal of providing an efficient and economic transportation system,
while at the same time trying to ensure that the public interest is protected
from transportation inequities. Do we need a new transportation policy to meet
our future needs? Perhaps the basic question that should be asked is can the
major problems and complaints be solved under the existing National
Transportation Act and it's policy? Certainly, the enactment of the NTA in 1967
has not stopped the complaints, especially from the West.
It would be impossible hereto deal adequately
with all the transport problems in the various regions of the country so we are
limiting the discussion to a few key issues in the West that keep recurring and
which will have to be resolved in order to have a viable transportation system
in the future. These include railroad freight rates; the Crowsnest Pass rates;
and grain shipment. The question of regional development will also be
interwoven throughout this discussion as it is a part of the development
process in the West. By looking at these issues we should be better able to
ascertain whether or not a new transportation policy is needed.
Freight Rates
One of the most hotly debated transportation
issues in the Prairies is that of railroad freight rates. The specific
complaints centre on three railway, rate relationship. The first alleges that
industries are charged higher rates on finished or processed goods than on raw
materials, and that this discriminatory rate relationship impedes the
development and growth of plants in the Prairies to process raw materials
produced there. It Is also believed that this discourages the secondary
processing of raw agricultural products, wheat, feed grains. malting barley and
oilseeds in the West. The second complaint alleges that because the railways
charge Prairie communities higher rates on steel products, canned goods and
other manufactured goods than the rates on the same commodities for the longer
hauls from central Canada to Vancouver, this long-short haul discrimination
favours the location of wholesaling, jobbing and manufacturing on the West
Coast rather than in the Prairies. Here, it is contended that the distance
advantage of the Prairies to and from Central Canada is disregarded in railway
rate-making. A third complaint is that the Prairies do not enjoy the advantage
of blanket or group rates to the extent that the railways have arranged such
rates for central Canada. Hence, while industrial development in small cities
in central Canada may be encouraged by group rates that give the smaller
population centres within a group the same rates as the large centres enjoy, it
is argued that the lack of similar application of group rates in the Prairies
hinders development in the smaller cities and towns. Finally, the West has
asserted that the directional level of freight rates accentuates the
concentration of manufacturing activities in Eastern Canada. It suggests that
the rates on westbound goods are lower than the rates on similar commodities
moving east.
The Prairies contend that these freight rate
problems restrict economic and industrial development in their region.
Recently, these allegations have come in for more study and analysis and we are
therefore able to make some observation about their validity. The question of
rates on raw materials versus finished products was examined in relation to the
meatpacking industry, in the West. It was found that unjust discrimination in
rail freight rates is not a detrimental factor in the development of this
industry in Alberta. What does seem to have a distorting effect on its location
is the low Crowsnest Pass rates on export grain. They encourage the shipment of
grain out of the West rather than keeping the grain there to feed cattle. As a
result, livestock production, and particularly feedlots, shifts away from the Prairies
and closer to centres of consumption such as Toronto and Vancouver. This means
that there are fewer livestock on the Prairies for the processing plants. The
effects of the Crowsnest Pass rates, then. is an anomaly under this heading
that needs attention. The general situation, however, does not seem to indicate
there are widespread freight rate inequities.
In the area of long and short-haul freight
pricing there appears to be some justification for the complaints. The
railroads justify charging higher rates to ship steel from Hamilton to Edmonton
than to Vancouver, as being necessary to enable them to retain or obtain
traffic in their more competitive terminal markets such as Vancouver at reduced
profit margins, without having to forego profits in their less competitive
interior markets by reducing rates there. This question has been the subject of
many investigations but no totally satisfactory solution has been reached. The
CTC has disallowed, or limited, the rise of these rates but they still occur.
When we examine the question of blanket
rates we find that these do exist in the West. They are mainly for resource
industries including sulphur, wood-pulp, lumber and potash. While the Western
resource industries enjoy these rates, the grouping structure available for
Western manufacturing is more limited than its Eastern counterpart. This is a
result of industrial development and transportation competition in Eastern
Canada. While the West wants more group ratings for manufacturing, studies do
not clearly indicate whether or not this would favour the development and
dispersion of industry in the West. So we are unable to ascertain the impact of
this situation on industrial development.
While more in-depth studies are needed in
this area, the evidence to date does not support the assertion that rates on
westbound goods are lower than the rates on similar commodities moving East. An
analysis of rail rates in 1974 showed that the average rail rate into Western
Canada from east of Thunder Bay was $52.62 per ton, compared with a rate of
$32.87 per ton in the reverse direction. This substantiates a 1973 study in
which it was found "that the lowest level of freight rates is for
movements emanating from the West." This no doubt partly reflects the effect
of the low Crowsnest Pass rates.
Therefore, some freight rate inequities do
exist but this does not appear to be an overall situation. Rather problems tend
to occur on a case-by-case basis and more negotiations between shippers and
railways should be able to resolve them failing that, the CTC can act on the
issue.
The responses to these freight rate concerns
have included Royal Commissions, the freezing of railway freight rates from
1973 to January 1975, the freight rate discussions of the Western Economic
Opportunities Conference in 1973 and CTC studies into freight rate anomalies.
As noted earlier, the studies showed that some concerns were shown to be real
while others were not as bothersome as once perceived. This does not mean that
the concerns have been solved; it merely means that they have been clarified to
a degree. Action still needs to be taken on specific items, such as long and
short-haul rates, before any long-term solution is reached.
Crowsnest Pass Rates
The railways are still carrying export grain
at these rates, which were first established in 1897 under an agreement between
Canada and the CPR and later extended to include all railroads. S I rice they
have obviously not kept pace with inflation, the railways are losing money by
carrying export grain at these rates. The CNR and CPR estimated their losses
for 1978 at approximately $175 million and both the Hall and Snayely
Commissions on railroads and grain transportation found that the railways lose
money carrying grain at these rates.
There is a strong belief among non-export
grain shippers that they pay higher rates to make up for what the railways lose
carrying grain at low statutory rates. This is substantiated to a degree by the
earlier example of the meatpacking industry, and some 1977 studies have also
shown that shippers of industrial products pay higher freight rates to make up
for the low "Crow Rate".
While these rates have helped Prairie grain
producers, they have also apparently had an adverse effect on producers of
processed goods in the West. Alleviation of the adverse nature of these rates
with compensation to the railways for their losses might help to reduce some of
the rate disparities they have caused.
Both the Hall and Snayely Commissions
recommended some form of compensation be made for these low rates either
through a federal subsidy to the railways or by payment directly to the grain
producers of the difference between the "Crow Rate" and the increase,
if the Crow Rate were allowed to rise. To date, no changes have taken place
regarding these rates although there seems to be a growing feeling in the West
that some changes in these rates are required.
Related to this is a more recent complaint
by Western grain producers to the railways and the Federal Government that the
transportation system for grain haulage is so poor that the total grain harvest
cannot be shipped to markets. There are complaints of poor rail equipment, lack
of hopper cars for grain, and rail bottlenecks at the elevators and export
ports.
The railways have admitted that they have
been reticent to upgrade their stock and to invest in new grain handling
equipment because they lose money hauling grain at Crowsnest Pass Rates. The
Federal Government has commissioned a number of studies into improving the
grain handling system. Their major recommendations have been calls for more
grain hopper cars, increased grain storage capacity at Prince Rupert,
rationalization of the collection of grain on the Prairies into fewer pickup
points, and for a solution to be found to the question of low Crowsnest Pass
rates.
As with freight rates, there have been some
moves to alleviate the situation. The Federal Government has purchased hopper
cars and helped the railways to pay for rehabilitating old boxcars in the grain
car fleet. In addition, negotiations with the Federal Government are taking
place over funding for the expansion of grain handling facilities at the port
of Prince Rupert. A grain traffic co-ordinator has also been appointed to help
ship the grain for export and to allocate grain cars for this purpose. This
would help to alleviate the rail bottlenecks and/ or lack of cars for grain
haulage that now occurs.
A New National Transportation Policy?
The previous section looked at three key
transportation issues, but they are by no means the only ones. They are,
however, important ones, ones that have been with us for a number of years, and
whose resolution is vital to the functioning of a sound transportation system
in the future. Their resolution is also critical for the economic wellbeing of
the West.
Does the solution to these problems lie in a
new national transportation policy? It appears that in most instances this is
unwarranted. The recommendations for solution, such is contained in the studies
on freight rates do not suggest a new national transportation policy. For
example, the problem with long and short-haul rates can be resolved by the CTC,
shippers and transportation companies coming to an agreement on rates. Failing
this, the CTC can act in the public interest to curtail these rates. Similarly,
the grain handling system can be improved through negotiations between the
various levels of government, producers and transportation companies to attain
a viable transport system.
In the case of the Crowsnest Pass Rates,
solutions have been proposed that may require changes in the Crowsnest Pass
Freight Rates Act. But here again, this does not require a new transportation
policy. It calls for reaction by the Government on a specific problem in transportation.
Moves to solve transport problems have taken place without a new policy and it
does not necessarily hold true that it cannot happen in the future. It would
seem that the policy established under the NTA has not failed; rather, it
appears that specific problems have failed to get the attention they merit.
Within any policy, there are bound to be some problems that arise and policy
cannot cover every contingency. It is the problems that need attention.
Changing policy will not necessarily solve these problems; it may merely change
the overall direction of transportation policy. What is required is specific
attention and remedies to specific problems and concerns. The revolution in
transportation may well be our resolution of these key transportation issues.
Without this, it is unlikely that we will be able to cope with future problems
that will undoubtedly arise in this area.