Stewart
Hyson is a political scientist in Saint John, New Brunswick.
In
1848 Nova Scotia was the first overseas jurisdiction of the former British
Empire to gain responsible government. Over the years a strong two-party
tradition prevailed and the province had little experience with minority
government although on a couple of occasions the Government had a very slim
majority. The election of March 24, 1998 produced a legislature with 19
Liberals, 19 New Democrats and 14 Progressive Conservatives. This
article looks at the political situation in Nova Scotia following the election.
It also reviews the literature on minority government in general and
concludes by suggesting that this minority situation may lead to a rebirth of
interest in the art of responsible government in Nova Scotia.
Following the 1998 election the
existing government led by Premier Russell MacLellan decided to remain in
office despite its greatly reduced numbers (19 instead of 39 seats).1 Premier MacLellan decided
to appoint a much smaller cabinet of 12 members and to proceed without entering
a coalition or negotiating a formal pact with either of the opposition parties.
Because the NDP had to fulfill its role as the Official Opposition much
of the attention has been and will be centred on the Conservatives as the
minority third party. In effect, the Liberal government has to depend on
the support of its arch rivals.
One of the first manifestations
of the new situation was the decision to elect the Speaker by secret ballot.
Opposition MLAs defeated the government’s nominee and succeeded in having
a Tory chosen as Speaker and an NDPer as Deputy Speaker. In both
legislative and budgetary matters the MacLellan government seems to be more
sensitive to the need to accommodate the opposition. The Public Accounts
Committee has been especially vigorous, although this might be due more to the
controversial allegation of political interference in respect to the province’s
casinos than the minority government situation.
Both the governing Liberals and
the Conservatives are aware of each other’s policy priorities, and have an
understanding of what it will take to make the minority government work.
Informal meetings and talks between key party leaders have been held frequently
since the March election and more can be expected. During the spring sitting,
compromises were made on many issues while the more divisive issues were
avoided. The critical question as to how long this informal arrangement can
last is obviously dependent on the circumstances that develop and the persons
involved. Actually, although much of the focus with minority government is on
what occurs inside the legislature, specifically on the relationships between
the government and opposition, everything is dependent on the situation outside
the legislature. Specifically, what counts is each party’s perception of its
relative standing with the electorate: would its representation increase or
decrease if a general election was called today?
Despite the political rhetoric
of adhering to party policies and not compromising principles on key issues, no
party has any desire to go to the polls again too shortly after a general
election, especially one that has resulted in a minority government. All parties
have to wonder and worry about the low turnout rate in the March election – at
approximately 70%, this represented a significant drop from the usual rate of
75%. Was one party hurt more severely than the others by its regular supporters
not voting or were the nonvoters evenly distributed across the ranks of all
three parties? What would happen if these nonvoters should decide to vote in
the next election?
Equally worrisome is the
question of money. It takes a considerable sum to conduct a modern election
campaign, and it is safe to say that no party in Nova Scotia at the moment has
the finances in place to hit the campaign trail again too soon after the last
election. Even the NDP, which made the greatest gains and seems to have
momentum on its side, probably has an empty campaign chest if it is not deeply
in debt from the last election campaign.
A close examination of the
election results at the constituency level also reveals why no party is inclined
to go to the polls too soon. Although the NDP did make the greatest gains, it
has to be guarded about its lack of appeal outside the Halifax metropolitan
area (where it won 13 of its seats). By taking only six seats and finishing
well behind in most constituencies in the rest of the province, what are the
NDP’s immediate prospects for improvement? The Liberals can take comfort in
winning its 19 seats in all parts of the province and by coming in second place
in 28 other districts. Still, the Liberal Party must be haunted by the
break-down of its traditional base of support and the loss of over half the
seats that it took into the March election. If another election was held within
a year, would more Liberal supporters jump ship and switch their votes
elsewhere?
It is the Conservative Party,
however, that finds itself in the deepest quandary. On the one hand, the party
was shut-out of both the Halifax area and on Cape Breton Island, with all of
its seats coming from the small-town and rural areas of mainland Nova Scotia.
Yet the Conservatives did much better than expected under the rustic leadership
of John Hamm, whose style stirred fond memories for many Nova Scotians of
Robert Stanfield’s stellar leadership of the Conservative party and province in
the 1950s and 1960s. But memories are not enough, and with little chance of
expanding its base of support in the next few months, the Conservatives have
the greatest incentive to cooperate with the Liberal Government.
There is thus every expectation
for all three parties to make this minority government work for now, but then
what can we expect? This is where the element of “iffiness” associated with
minority government comes into play as to its durability, efficiency, and
effectiveness. Will the Nova Scotia legislature be short-lived with a new
election held sooner than usual? Yes, on both points. But what is meant by a
short-lived legislature – a few months, a year or two, or longer? Except to say
anything less than the norm of four years, the possibilities are infinite. The
Liberal minority government could work both smoothly and progressively with the
opposition-dominated legislature for a reasonable period, like the 1972-74
federal minority government of Pierre Trudeau. Alternatively, it could be as ineffective
as that of Joe Clark’s election in 1979.
Much will depend on the
willingness of the participants to compromise and cooperate in respect to their
disparate policy preferences. At the same time, it is necessary to keep in mind
that the Nova Scotia Legislature is only in session for a few weeks each year;
for example, the spring session went from May 21 to the end of June. So, it is
not as if the government will face defeat each and every day for 365 days a
year (or for any period longer than a few weeks).
The government could even
survive the legislative defeat of some of its minor bills as long as it
retained the legislature’s majority support on a vote of confidence.
What would happen if the
government was defeated on a vote of confidence or on an important piece of
legislation (such as the budget)? The government would have to resign with the
premier advising Llieutenant-Governor James Kinley to dissolve the legislature
and to call a new election. Most likely the lieutenant-governor would follow
through with this advice, especially now that the government has survived the
spring sitting and had its budget approved. If it had been otherwise, however,
the lieutenant-governor could have avoided an election by asking Robert
Chisholm of the NDP if he had the legislative support of the Conservatives to
form a government. Although such an option would have been highly unusual, it
is prudent not to overlook the Crown’s authority in this situation, especially
given the comparable strength of the NDP and Liberals in both seats and popular
vote. But once the first sitting had successfully passed, the viability of this
option from then on was quickly discredited as being too autocratic for our
times, and experience suggests that the lieutenant-governor will have to follow
the premier’s advice.
In any case, for the reasons
cited above, Nova Scotia’s minority government can now be expected to last at
least a year and probably longer. Besides the question of longevity, the more
pressing question is that of performance. Just how effective will Nova Scotia’s
minority government be? Will it be weak and unstable or more responsive? It is
impossible to suggest with any degree of certainty what will unfold in the
province. But we can reflect upon minority government in the broader context of
parliamentary responsible government.
Minority Government in
Canada: Literature Review
C.E.S. Franks has conveniently
summarized the traditional (and negative) thinking about minority government:
The arguments are often made that
majority government is not only natural and proper, but also the most
efficient, and that the lines of responsibility and accountability in minority
parliaments are blurred because smaller parties have an undue influence.2
Although still not the norm,
minority government does seem to be occurring more frequently both federally
and provincially since the late 1950s. As a consequence, there has been a
change in public attitudes in respect to minority government. Familiarity with
this institution has led to less suspicion and fear, to be replaced by a more
open willingness to acknowledge its strengths. Thus, rather than automatically
assuming minority government to be weak and unstable, there is now the alternative
tendency to view it as being more responsive to the wishes of the legislators
and electorate. This is the situation faced today as we reflect on the
institution of minority government: weak and unstable or more responsive? It is
a question that can only be settled by empirical study, rather than a reliance
on myths and half-truths.
For this purpose, there is
probably no better place to start than with Eugene Forsey’s 1964 article on the
issue of minority government.3
Admittedly, this article is overly legalistic and historical in content, with
examples drawn from Great Britain, Australia, and New Zealand as well as from
Canada. But, and this is the critical point, Forsey did authoritatively
challenge (and dismiss) the objections commonly made about minority government,
especially the notion that it was ill-suited to deal effectively with the
complex issues encountered by governments in the 20th century. His
concluding sentence is especially intriguing: “Minority government can be not a
”problem" but an opportunity, not a threat but a promise."4
This point is centred on the
nature of the Westminster model of parliamentary responsible government, in
terms of how the executive (or cabinet) and legislature coexist in a state of
cooperation.5 In simple terms
the task of the cabinet is to propose legislation (or to govern) while the
legislature’s task is to review, debate, and approve that legislation (and
performance). In normal times when one party wins a majority of seats in the
legislature, there is no problem because the majority party leader becomes the
prime minister or premier who chooses cabinet ministers from the ranks of the
party’s elected members. Party discipline then allows the government to achieve
approval of its legislation while also allowing suitable opportunity for
legislative scrutiny and debate. But in a situation where no party has a
majority of seats in the legislature, executive-legislative cooperation is more
difficult but not impossible to achieve which raises the question: how?
Linda Geller-Schwartz has noted
that, in a situation where no party commands a majority of seats, there are
five possible modes of executive-legislative cooperation.6 First, two or more parties with
representatives in the legislature may form a coalition government, with each
party having ministers in the cabinet and contributing policies as part of the
government’s legislative programme. A second arrangement would be a formal
pact, where a smaller third party does not have membership in the cabinet but
publicly agrees in writing to support another party in government for a limited
period of time in exchange for specified policy concessions from the governing
party.
Both of these modes in fact have
been rare occurrences in Canada. Ian Stewart has correctly observed that the
only federal coalition government was that formed in 1917, and that was due to
the wartime emergency rather than a minority parliament situation.7 Provincially, Manitoba had
coalition government between 1932 and 1958, as did British Columbia from 1941
to 1952. The only example of a formal pact was that in Ontario (1985-87)
between David Peterson’s Liberals, with the second largest number of seats, and
the third-place NDP of Bob Rae.8 While
both the coalition government and formal pact modes have seldom been followed
in this country, the same cannot be said for the other three modes identified
by Geller-Schwartz.
An “informal understanding”
between a governing party and a third party can exist in place of a formal
agreement. In effect, by sizing-up the situation, the party that forms the
government knows that it can count on a third party’s support by introducing
some legislation consistent with the latter’s policy priorities; in return, the
third party recognizes that, in exchange for its support, it can expect
favourable policy accommodation from the government. Practical astuteness thus
replaces the need for a formal agreement. Geller-Schwartz identifies the fourth
mode as “ad hoc majorities” where the government makes a separate accommodation
with the opposition parties on each bill. The fifth mode is where both
governing and opposing parties go through the pretense as if a majority
government situation exists and opposition members exercise self-restraint on
critical votes in the legislature usually by being away on other parliamentary
business.
Although experience suggests
that these three informal modes are the common practice in Canada, they are
usually less visible involving as they do the subtle working relationships
amongst members of the same institution. This reality, in fact, suggests why
the distinction between the three categories is often blurred to the outside
observer, and why all three may coexist in the same minority government
situation.
An Opportunity Worthy of Consideration
Is minority government less
efficient than majority government? One of the old saws often heard about
minority government is that it is less efficient because of the need to devote
more time to legislative debate in order to accommodate opposing views. This is
a most peculiar argument for several reasons. In the first place, scholars
including Eugene Forsey have demonstrated that less efficiency need not be the
case. Minority government may be both efficient as well as progressive in terms
of its policy accomplishments. In addition, this old-line position overlooks
one of the major weaknesses with majority government, where the government is
able to ramrod its bills through the legislature with legislators reduced to
being little more than political eunuchs. If this is what is meant by a more
efficient legislature, then is it desirable? The truth of the matter is that it
is not all that relevant as to how much or how quickly legislation is approved
by a legislature in one session – that is a numbers game.
The issue of legislative
performance is much more complex and cannot (and should not) be reduced to the
efficiency criterion.
Perhaps the greatest fault of
the efficiency argument, however, is that it perversely dismisses the original
role of parliament as a place to talk. More correctly, it is not just a matter
of talking but the ability to exchange ideas in a civilized manner. There is
value to be found in the orderly exchange of ideas in the open forum provided
by the legislature, as a key stage in the democratic development of public
policy. Legislative debate is central to the Westminster model of parliamentary
government, where the cabinet governs but is also subject to legislative
scrutiny. If any doubt remains as to the importance of meaningful legislative
debate, then one should look back at the experience in New Brunswick following
the 1987 election when the Liberals won all legislative seats leaving the
opposition parties without an official presence.9
This is obviously a fine balance, balancing the executive and legislative
roles, that may be easily thrown out of kilter.
It would be tempting at this
juncture to expound on how and why the Nova Scotia Legislative Assembly has
become an executive-dominated institution, and needs to be reformed so as to
redress the balance in favour of the legislature. In this sense, the Nova
Scotia Legislature is not much unlike its counterparts in the rest of the
country.10
Conclusion
Minority government, in effect,
has the potential to make parliamentary responsible government work the way it
was supposed to work by allowing for greater input by MLAs. Yes, of course,
there will be more legislative debate because of the need to accommodate a
greater diversity of viewpoints; in fact this has already been the case in Nova
Scotia. At the same time, we must fix in our heads that there is nothing wrong
with more debate; rather, open debate is consistent with the democratic ideals
upon which our political system is based. The executive will have to work more
earnestly at mobilizing legislative support for its policies, just as the MLAs
will have to ensure the executive’s ability to govern. Minority government to
succeed thus requires a change of attitude on the part of all those involved.
This is easier said than achieved because the existing norms of legislative
behaviour held by politicians are firmly entrenched and were developed in the
context of majority government.
When it comes to a minority
government situation, the key objective would seem to be how best to remove the
dark cloud of uncertainty. The soundest routes would probably be either the
coalition or formal pact modes. Both would allow for greater, meaningful
legislative input, while also facilitating the executive’s ability to govern
without the uncertainty of being defeated at any moment. At the same time, the
openness of both modes would clearly identify the line of accountability in
respect to policy accomplishments and failures. Of the two modes, the formal
pact would probably be the more feasible. Except for an emergency situation,
parties would probably be unwilling to sacrifice completely their
individualities by joining a coalition. Besides, in the eyes of many, coalition
government is perceived to be foreign to, or incompatible with, the Westminster
model of parliamentary responsible government. However, the formal pact allows
parties to retain their separate identities in both organizational and policy
terms, while placing their partisan differences on hold for a specified period
of time yet also achieving definite policy goals.
Neither of these modes, however,
received much consideration in Nova Scotia as the parties were content to rely
upon informal, ad hoc tactics. Perhaps it was because of the novelty of
minority government in the province that a more formal arrangement was avoided.
Or perhaps, the partisan and/or ideological differences were too great to be
bridged. Coalition theory would facilitate greatly any probe of what happened
and why in Nova Scotia.11 Given
the extent of the Nova Scotia electorate’s fragmentation, and its increased
voting volatility in recent years, there is every likelihood of more minority
governments in the province’s future. If this should happen, the opportunity
should be taken to consider the adoption of the formal pact mode. This mode has
the potential to allow parliamentary responsible government to function
effectively with a minority dominated legislature.
Notes
1. For personal reasons, one NDP MLA left the
party caucus to sit as an Independent. Thus, the actual standings in the 57th
Legislative Assembly were: 19 Liberal, 19 NDP, 13 Progressive Conservatives,
and 1 Independent.
2. C.E.S. Franks, The
Parliament of Canada (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1987), p. 48.
3. Eugene Forsey, “The Problem
of ‘Minority’ Government in Canada”, Canadian Journal of Economics and
Political Science, Vol. XXX no. 1 (February 1964), pp. 1-11.
4. Ibid., p. 11.
5. C.E.S. Franks, especially pp.
10-15.
6. Linda Geller-Schwartz,
“Minority Government Reconsidered”, Journal of Canadian Studies, Vol. 14
no. 2 (summer 1979), pp. 67-79. (For another set of propositions concerning
federal minority parliaments, see the Stewart reference mentioned in the next
endnote, pp. 452-57.)
7. Ian Stewart, “Of Customs and
Coalitions: The Formation of Canadian Federal Parliamentary Alliances,” Canadian
Journal of Political Science, Vol. XIII no. 3 (September 1980), p. 453,
note 5.
8. A copy of this formal pact
may be found in the first edition of Rand Dyck’s Provincial Politics in
Canada (Scarborough: Prentice-Hall Canada Inc., 1986), pp. 325-27.
9. Stewart Hyson, “Where’s ‘Her Majesty’s
Loyal Opposition’ in the Loyalist Province?”, Canadian Parliamentary Review,
Vol. 11, No. 2 (Summer 1988) pp. 22-25.
10. For a general discussion of
parliamentary reform, see Franks, especially pp. 10-34 and 257-69; for an
earlier specific account on Nova Scotia, see Michael M. Atkinson, “Reform and
Inertia in the Nova Scotia Assembly,” Journal of Canadian Studies, Vol.
14, No. 2 (Summer 1979), pp. 133-41.
11. For an insightful account of
coalition theory in respect to minority government, see Stewart, pp. 451-79.