At the time this article was
written Charles A. Ruud was a professor of history at the University of Western
Ontario in London, Ontario.
On January 1, 1992, the Soviet
Union was replaced by a new Commonwealth of Independent States. The largest,
most powerful of the new states is Russia and the new situation has given rise
to much discussion about the long term prospects for western style
parliamentary democracy in Russia. The problems and possibilities are often
discussed without a full appreciation of the ongoing struggle in Russian
history between Slavophil (nationalistic) forces on the one hand and
pro-western forces on the other. In this article an historian looks at previous
attempts to establish representative and parliamentary institutions in Russia.
Today and throughout their history,
the Russian people have mainly done without parliaments, even as they have
adopted many other procedural forms from the West. Why this disinterest and
even nonchalance? The usefulness of absolutism to autocrats in power is, of
course, one cause, but so is entrenched ideology--that holds that the Russian
psyche and absolutism are uniquely compatible.
Examined historically, Russian autocracy
has its origins in the medieval Muscovite Tsardoms. But not until the reign of
a tsar conventionally described as a reformer--Peter I "the Great"
(1682-1725)--did it acquire its mature and enduring absolutist form. Although
from time to time advised and assisted by various institutions, Peter (who
preferred the European title of Emperor) established that he alone held final
power to decide and promulgate laws and decrees.
Nor would Peter ever have
entertained the notion of bowing to a higher moral code on human rights. His
ruling prerogative stood paramount, and he used it for arming Russia and for
requiring his subjects to pay the bill. Peter and his eighteenth century
successors, including the "enlightened" Catherine II, took for
granted their right to squeeze out of their subjects (most of whom were serfs
in a condition of chattel bondage) whatever they needed for their monumental
projects.
Early in the reign of Alexander I
(1801-1825), ideas emanating from France on the rights of man caused a ripple
of discussions within high state councils--and even on the pages of the few
periodicals, all fully censored--about introducing some form of representative
government. One striking result in 1809 was a project for constitutional change
by M.M. Speransky, an advisor to the Tsar, who proposed that a narrow group of
voters from the land- and serf-owning class elect local legislative assemblies.
Above that level were to be three higher tiers of assemblies, each elected from
and by the one below.
Only the national assembly, the
Duma, would "initiate" legislation, and it could exercise that right
solely should the autocratic government 1) encroach on the very limited rights
of citizens or 2) fail to present a budget on time. In proposing very little for
the Duma to do, Speransky ostensibly took care not to place the tsar in the
"unpleasant" position of having to reject Duma legislation. But, more
to the point, he knew that proposing any larger legislative role for the Duma
would certainly fail to win approval from the tsar and his ministers.
Still a partisan of eighteenth
century ideas of gradual--and therefore orderly--progress in the wake of the
cataclysmic excesses of the French revolution, Speransky put forward his
minimalist "constitutional" plan as a modest first step in creating
elective bodies from the landowning elite subordinate to the autocrat. His
opponents, however, responded by raising doubts about Speransky's long-term
commitment to the autocracy and thereby convinced Alexander to exile his advisor
from St. Petersburg. Little of his reform program survived and, following the
Napoleonic wars and the failed liberal rebellion by the Decembrists in 1825,
Russia abandoned any plans for legislative reform.
During the second quarter of the
nineteenth century, the reigning Emperor Nicholas I (1825-55) adamantly opposed
anything akin to a constitution (the word itself was banned in the heavily
censored press) and deliberately promulgated the idea that a parliament was a
Western institution alien to higher Russian values. The Tsar's propagandists
insisted not only that the Russian people innately loved their Tsar, but also
that their deeper spiritual life had given rise to the Autocracy. Elected
representative legislatures, in contrast, were institutional expressions of the
inferior Western culture which promoted ongoing struggles for advantage by
pitting one group against another. Besides, the argument went, such
institutions only fraudulently claimed to provide participatory democracy
because they did not truly represent the people as a whole.
Russia had found a better way, said
the Slavophil thinker, Ivan Kireevsky: "In Russia laws were not formulated
in advance by some learned jurists; they were not ponderously and eloquently
discussed at some legislative assembly; and they did not subsequently fall like
an avalanche in the midst of the astounded citizenry, wrecking some existing
institution or custom of theirs." Rather, Kireevsky insisted, Russian law
formed first as folk wisdom in the minds of the people. Making use of those
truths as benevolent legislators, the tsars over time wisely decreed into law
only those instruments and procedures that met the broad needs and desires of
the people. (The Slavophils contended that the institution of the Autocrat was a
brilliant example of Russian political thinking, in that its placement of all
power in the hands of one ruler freed everyone else from the contaminations of
political life.)
Such ideas, of course, rationalized
national superiority--especially for the Slavophils. In Russia alone had the
heretofore silent masses long and unostentatiously been creating the best
political and cultural institutions in the world. Westernized Russian
intellectuals, with their penchant for French ideas, were to be pitied, at best,
for never having noticed.
In the years before Kireevsky made
his case, the Autocracy had already very dramatically expressed its displeasure
with Westernizers. In 1836 the head of state security had dealt severely with
Peter Chaadaev for being the author of a published letter that belittled
Russia. With the three-fold effect of discrediting, isolating, and punishing
him, officials had Chaadaev certified "insane" and subjected to home
confinement with daily visits by a doctor. The hapless author protested that
his words--contained in private letters to friends--had been published without
his knowledge or consent. But he could not dispute their message: that backward
and sterile Russia had contributed nothing to world culture. In 1837, a
chastened Chaadaev wrote "Apology of a Madman" to prophecy a bright
future for Russia.
During the reign of Tsar Alexander
II (1855-81), a series of liberal changes raised hopes that the autocrat would
introduce some kind of legislative, representative assembly. His liberation of
the some 40 million serfs and his reforms of local government, the judiciary,
censorship, and education were decidedly Western. He did not--in the liberal
jargon of the day--"crown the edifice" with a parliament. Events and
advisors prevented that institutional change.
P.A. Valuev, the Minister of the
Interior, was one such advisor. From the start of his tenure, he openly
deplored that some of his compatriots, viewing the advance of legislative
assemblies in western Europe, argued that "it should therefore be the same
with us." Instead, held Valuev, the Russian landed gentry must realize its
political ambitions in the new institution of local government, the zemstvo.
Here the gentry would be "the principal collaborators" of the autocracy.
As for some semblance of a legislature in the capital, Valuev suggested
modifying the State Council to incorporate representatives from the gentry
class who would merely advise the government on legislative projects. But
nothing of the sort took place.
Influential thinkers outside the
tsar's government bolstered Valuev's stand against replicating a Western
parliament, one being Boris Chicherin. In 1866, this historian at Moscow
University, who would later serve as mayor of Moscow, issued a book entitled
Popular Representation to insist on limiting that political form to the local
zemstvo, as did Valuev. Chicherin held that the absolutist monarchy would
thereby avoid both the excesses of popular despotism (he was thinking of the
rule of Napoleon III) and the crippling chaos of western-type party strife. He
did interject that the Autocracy, in accord with "national
tradition," must be subject to law, but he stressed overall that no step
be taken to alter the unilateral, patriarchal government that made Russia great.
One of Valuev's successors as
Minister of the Interior, M.T. Loris-Melikov, repeated Valuev's proposal for
gentry consultants on the State Council in 1880 and urged, as well, the
creation of a new General Commission that could therefore be described as
"representational." Such reformist measures, he contended, would
blunt the charges of revolutionaries that the autocracy gave the people no
voice in government and would offset the repressive measures he had to take
against the mounting terrorist movement.
Citing the low "moral level of
society" as cause for granting only to the upper class the right to elect
state-level representatives, Loris-Melikov favoured seating such
representatives (elected by the zemstvos) in a consultative--certainly not a
legislative--assembly to be called a General Commission. Completing the
membership would be legal and policy experts appointed by the tsar, and the
Commission as a whole, meeting in regular sessions, would make recommendations
to the Council of State.
Alexander II decided to implement
Loris-Melikov's plan for the General Commission. By chance, the day he was to
announce this innovation to the public was also the day that the eighth
terrorist attempt in 17 months to kill the tsar succeeded.
Retrenchment followed under Tsar
Alexander III (1881-1894), whose chief advisor for a series of
"counter-reforms" was the reactionary K.P. Pobedonostsev. This
official, who had a totally mordant view of human possibilities, held that only
strong rule from the top could save the fundamentally depraved Russian people.
As for parliaments, the claim put forth by liberals that such bodies somehow
"represented" the people, he scoffed, was "the great lie of our
time."
Under the next and final
tsar--Nicholas II (1894-l917)--emerged, at last, a popularly-elected, national
legislative body, the Duma, that can fairly be called a parliament. After a
fractious start, it would prove to do the work a parliament is supposed to
do--a distinction that makes it unique in the history of the Russian people.
Nicholas II at no point welcomed a
parliament, a position he made clear at the very start of his reign by terming
a zemstvo appeal for "public institutions" as "senseless
dreams." But, as his security agency sent him more and more warnings of
spreading dissatisfaction with the autocracy and as overt protests mounted to
become the Revolution of 1905, Nicholas was forced to relent.
In his manifesto of 30 October
1905, Nicholas II promised the creation of a Russian parliament, or Duma; and
he shortly followed up with an electoral law for the Duma that enfranchised
almost all male property owners. By including the millions of male peasants who
held title to their small plots, the autocrat wrongly expected to shape a
voting majority that would seat a strongly conservative Duma. Instead the
voters chose representatives of every stripe from right to left, ensuring that
the initial Duma--and the one that followed--would be little more than a
battlefield for airing bitter political and ideological differences. On the eve
of the second Duma, easily sensing what lay ahead, the Tsar wrote with some
smugness to his mother: "...it will soon be evident whether the Duma
intends to get down to serious work or to squander its time and small prestige
in useless chatter and abuse."
As for the powers in the hands of
the Duma when it first convened in April of 1906, the tsar's government had by
then transformed the State Council into an upper house whose assent was
required before any legislation passed by the Duma, or lower house, became law.
Designed to be safely conservative, the Council acquired half its membership
through appointments made by the tsar and half through elections held in
various institutions acceptable to him. The Tsar--he continued to call himself
Autocrat--claimed superiority to both houses; and, besides controlling
one-third of the national budget and holding final veto power over their joint
legislation, he additionally reserved to himself alone the right to revise the
Fundamental Laws, including those that spelled out the power of the Duma.
Justified by legislative
stalemates, Nicholas prorogued the first two Dumas of 1906 and 1907 within a
few months of their beginnings and then called new elections. In the second
instance, the tsar's prime minister, P.A. Stolypin, breached existing laws to
disenfranchise many peasants and members of minority nationalities in what is
called the "electoral coup d'état" of 16 June 1907. What resulted was
the relatively conservative Third Duma (the only Duma to last the full five
years of its mandated term), which accomplished a series of constructive
legislative programs, especially in 1908, 1909, and 1910. The government and
the Duma were at last sufficiently like-minded to work together.
In 1911, the terrorist who killed
Prime Minister Stolypin deprived Imperial Russia of its last truly effective
statesman; and the Fourth Duma, elected in 1912, fell into bitter conflict with
the tsar's government--especially after the outbreak of war with Austria and
Germany. The influence in high places of the Rasputin, sponsored by the
German-born tsarina Alexandra Fëdorovna (whose own allegiance to Russia fell
into question), strained relations even further.
By the time of the first revolution
of l917 (in March), the Duma--having found it impossible to work with the
Tsar's government after 1915--had virtually ceased to function. Because the
revolution put an end to the tsar, who agreed to abdicate, what followed next
was government by a Temporary Committee, self-created by a group of Duma liberals.
These eleven men were bent on holding the country together to defeat Germany
and determined to postpone during the wartime crisis a democratic vote for a
Constituent Assembly, eventually scheduled for November.
It is important to note here that the
Temporary Committee, which on 15 March 1917 renamed itself the Provisional
Government, in no way constituted a parliament. Essentially it was a
revolutionary dictatorship which could not govern. The unrelieved suffering
from food and fuel shortages at the front and at home in the harsh winter of
1916-17 caused broad indifference among the Russian people to an ad hoc
government that could not meet its basic needs. Lacking solutions to the
combined military, economic, and social crises, the Provisional Government
muddled on as anarchy deepened.
Because more and more Russians
began listening to the promises from radical socialist parties--especially the
Bolsheviks of Lenin--that they would end the war, transfer the land of the rich
to the poor, transfer capitalists' factories to the workers, and transform
Russia into a workers' democracy, a nascent and aggressively contentious centre
of power made itself felt. Its base was the cross-province network of Soviets
(councils) of Workers' Deputies begun during the Revolution of 1905. In the
November revolution of 1917, a virtually unopposed Lenin and his Bolsheviks
seized power in the name of the Second All-Russian Congress of Soviets meeting
in St. Petersburg.
Because he had long argued for a
Constituent Assembly, that is, a constitutional convention, and had criticized
the Provisional Government for putting off the election of delegates until
November, Lenin had no choice but to order that the election, based on
universal suffrage, go forward as scheduled. In what would be the most
democratic election ever held in Russia, the liberals and democrats saw their
last chance for a genuine constitutionalism, even as they doubted that they
could win.
Russian Word, a major liberal daily
in Moscow, summed up the impending election dilemma in these words: "In
another country, not so immense, with a population more cultured and
politically developed, the task of electing a constituent assembly would not
present special difficulties. It is another matter in Russia with its almost
universally illiterate people, immense spaces, terrible communications, and
polyglot population, especially under conditions of war."
When the votes were counted, the
party that emerged with an absolute majority, or 370 out of 707 seats was the
one that had most directly appealed to the peasants--the Social
Revolutionaries--and four-fifths of all the ballots cast favoured socialist
candidates of one kind or another. While the share of the total for the
Bolsheviks amounted to only 23.8 percent, the Constitutional Democrats won a
mere 4.6 percent of the votes and the seats. The Russian people had voted
overwhelmingly against the major proponents of parliamentary government.
The first session of the
Constituent Assembly met in St. Petersburg on 17 January 1918 and did not break
its deliberations until 5 a.m. the next morning. When delegates returned to
reconvene at noon on the 18th, armed troops from Lenin's Bolshevik government
informed them that their work had ended and forcibly turned them away. Among
the people of the new "workers' state," that abrupt conclusion to the
long-sought democratic assembly was met with massive indifference.
No true parliament emerged under
the Communist government that ruled the Soviet people for the next seventy-one
years. Stalin's Supreme Soviet belongs in the realm of political theatre, not
legislative government. Following the dissolution of the Soviet Union on
January 1, 1992, power has shifted to the newly sovereign republics and their
legislative bodies.
Russians may yet build a
parliamentary tradition, but a necessary ingredient for such a tradition, so
far unmentioned here, is still in short supply among the Russian people. That
essential is common trust. Because the past seven decades of Communist rule,
have taught the Russian people not to trust the top holders of power,
indifference about having or not having a parliament is a natural consequence.
Will the view of the Slavophils in the days of the tsars that politics were
intrinsically contaminated carry over into today's truism that public
involvement in politics, including parliaments, is pointless?