At the time this article was
written Robin M. LeBlanc was a Carl Albert Graduate Fellow at the Carl Albert
Congressional Research and Studies at the university of Oklahoma in Norman,
Oklahoma. LeBlanc specializes in the study of politics in advanced industrial
democracies, concentrating specifically on the politics of the United States
and Japan.
In the United States, as in Canada,
all legislation must be adopted in identical form by both Houses. Unlike Canada
the Americans make extensive use of conference committees to resolve
differences between the chambers. So important are these meetings to the
legislative process they have been called the fourth branch of government. Most
studies of conference committees focus on the narrower issue of "who
wins". This article uses three case studies to examine the congressional
conference as a legislative institution in its own right.
No one can say for sure which chamber
wins conferences or what conferences a particular chamber can win or why either
chamber would win over the other. Certainly the list of who-wins might be
trimmed or categorized according to the methodology adopted. However it would
be a tiresome task of minimum benefit. As Richard Fenno has recognized, the
problem of making an accurate and quantitative measure of a chamber's
conference success is not a small one.
We cannot know what `winning' means
unless we know the preferences of the two sides (and preferably those of each
conferee) with regard to the various amendments at issue. If, for example, one
group is willing to give up an item costing $50 million to get some especially
valued item costing $10 million, dollars and cents measures will be inadequate
to define winning.1
Even if some methodology could
account for the most complicated configurations of preference, the "Who
wins?" study is very limited. When we consider the myriad of differences
that must exist between bills which would be tallied to establish any empirical
sense of who-wins conferences, we must realize knowing which chamber dominate
does not mean we know much about the results of the legislative process.
Knowing who wins does not enable us
to answer one of the gravest questions of congressional studies. How does the
conference process either help or hinder the development of genuinely good
policy?
Wihout a doubt, conference
committees are key players in the legislative process. The use, since the early
80s of mega-conferences with over 200 conferees makes it apparent that
conference committees are legislatures in and of themselves. The bills which
would not have passed without conference committees to eradicate the
incoherencies of House and Senate versions are among the most important bills
in American history. The Bill of Rights, for instance, became part of the
Constitution only after going to conference.
While just 10 to 15 percent of
bills in a given year require conferences, this 10 to 15 percent could easily
be considered the most important bills Congress passes. Conference committee
reports must be voted either up or down by a chamber under a closed rule. If
they are voted down, the bills have to be recommitted. Time constraints are
usually such that the conference report must be voted up of a bill is ever to
reach the president. Conferees often attach substantively new provisions to a
bill despite rules requiring conference changes to remain within the scope of
the original legislation.
Conference committees do more than
reconcile different versions of the same bill. Since their opening to the
public under 1975 reforms, conferences act as nodes for special interest groups
to exert their influence on the policy process. Interest groups have managed to
obtain their desired policy outcomes more often since the conferences were
opened. Advice from executive officials may carry weight in conferences where
decisions can be complicated by the need to obtain consensus (and consensus
that does not get a presidential veto) on seemingly irreconcilable issues.
Staff, accessible to lobbyists and used to draft details of the more pedestrian
compromises or to provide area expertise, can also be influential.
Some evidence suggests conference
committees can affect the legislative process before the bill which will go to
conference has been written. The certainty that budget resolutions will
eventually end up in conference sets in motion a process of House-Senate
negotiations while the bills are still in the markup stage. Members
dissatisfied with the resolution drafted in their chamber may work deals with
members of the other chamber in hopes of getting what they want in conference.
An understanding of the predisposition of the other chamber may affect the
progress of the resolution in the home chamber.
Despite the emphasis bargaining
behaviour places on winning for the parent chamber, the conferees' strategies
are usually directed towards a common goal-compromise.
Members' voting choices on bills in
their own houses could be influenced by knowledge that they would be members of
a conference later on where they could hope to change the bill to reflect their
own wishes.
Even the most stalwart conferees
are really taking strategic stances. The realm of possible stances includes
stating unbroachable commitments to certain items in a bill and the proferring,
as concessions, of expendable items in the bill. Conferees employ threats, for
example the threat of seeking instructions from a parent chamber. Sometimes the
threats are of mutual destruction, such as when conferees announce they will
walk out on negotiations altogether if parts of the final bill fail to
accommodate their chamber's wishes. Conferees also draw on a variety of debts
and promises hinged on the fact that conferences between the same legislators,
albeit not over the same bill, are a constantly recurring event.
Compromise in conference is not
always easy. Congress is better at distributing resources than it is at
redistributing them. The most expedient means of achieving conference compromise
would require everyone in conference to receive at least part of what they
asked for–essentially a strategy of distribution. But today such a strategy is
not possible. With the current emphasis on fiscal restraint, budget conferences
act to redistribute rather than simply distribute. The redistribution problem
is not limited to budget conferences. Even conferences more oriented towards
policy than fiscal concerns are forced to recognize the need for a sort of
redistribution. Not every proposed program can be included in a law; the money
to pay for them all just does not exist.
The difficulty of redistribution
may heighten some qualities of conference compromise making the conference a
substatively different legislative arena than the chamber. Chambers may be more
inward-looking than conferences. Even when redistribution is called for,
chambers may be prone to practice distribution. Distribution is by nature
inclusive. It is the easiest way to win solid majorities for a legislative
program, and no intro-chamber check and balance system exists to make sure that
legislative programs adhere to fiscal realities. A Conference, however, does
call a check and balance system into play. One chamber is checked by the other.
But, even more important, a conference forces Congress to conceive of itself as
a single part of a whole government system where checks can come from a variety
of sources. In conference, a bill must be produced that will not only satisfy
the two chambers, but will also demonstrate congressional policy-making
legitimacy to external forces. A president whose rhetoric sings of fiscal
restraint and a public concerned with the tight fiscal realities can define the
value of a policy by its ability to redistribute in accordance with budget
constraints. Correspondingly, the value of a policy can define the legitimacy
of Congress as a policy-maker.
Introducing the Congressional
Context
Conferees draw the motives of their
actions from three contexts, individual, committee and institutional.2
They act, in conference, in ways that will accrue power to themselves, their
committee and their chamber. Perhaps another context should be added to the
list–the congressional context. In the congressional context conferees act to
accrue power for the legislative branch of government. It is not hard to see
that the demands of the congressional context might conflict with the demands
of the individual, committee and institutional contexts. The latter three
contexts may occasionally levy conflicting demands on a conferee but they have
something very significant in common. Individual, committee and institutional
contexts are all likely to require power of a "getting nature". To be
successful most easily within these three contexts, the conferee attempts to
receive the best distribution of benefits. For instance, if a conferee could
secure an appropriation or program which put federal funds into his district,
he would satisfy the demands of the individual context. And, unless he stood
against the majority preference of his chamber's delegation, he would also be
satisfying the committee and institutional contexts' demands.
The demands of the individual,
committee and institutional contexts are thus often fulfilled through acts of
distribution. These contexts militate a decentralization of decision-making.
Each conferee has a slightly different set of contextual demands, so, to a
certain extent, each conferee could benefit the most by acting alone. But
conferences do not accentuate the power of individual actors. In conference,
agreement, not difference, is the goal, and currently, resdistribution, not
distribution is the theme.
Conference committees are more than
arenas for the "getting" ethic of the individual, committee and
institutional contexts. Conference committees are also playing fields where the
reputation of Congress is on the line. When a bill does not come out of
conference it does not come out of Congress. Without such legislation as goes
to conference, Congress would be nothing more than the most rudimentary player
in the broad system of government. When legislators act according to the
confines of this understanding, they can be said to be acting in a
congressional context.
Unlike the other three contexts,
the congressional context demands centralized decision-making. Congress can
only have one voice. In deficit days, the congressional context ethic is …
"giving up," not "getting" as it is in the other three
contexts. Congress does not want to be known as the irresponsible, incapable
policy-maker. While the individual and committee contexts dominate on the
chamber floor, they are necessarily subverted to the congressional context in
conference. Even the institutional context must take a back seat to the
congressional context if compromise, (thus a bill)is to be achieved.
The hegemony of the congressional
context makes conference a better arena for redistributive politics than the
chamber. Because the ethic of the congressional context is giving up,
conferences are imbued with an atmosphere which supports tough choices. Because
the demand of the congressional context is centralization, conferences allow
for the strong leadership necessary for making tough choices. Finally, the
congressional context promotes its own survival by acting as a good excuse for
conferees. By acknowledging the primary need of conference is to produce a
bill, conferees can espouse the logic of the congressional context to explain
why they felt it necessary to compromise the preferences of constituents,
committee or chamber. As one writer explained at the end of the 1986 tax reform
conference:
The confereess had, in fact, gone
into their closed sessions for much the same reason that Congress passed the
Gramm-Rudman-Hollings anti-deficit law: It was an acknowledgement of a need to
be saved from themselves and their own habit of yielding to outside pressures.
With Rostenkowski and Packwood delegated to figure out a compromise, individual
conferees could tell angry constituents and contributors that they had little
or no control over the decisions.3
The Case Studies
In three conferences, the 1986 tax
reform conference, the FY 1988 deficit reduction conference and the 1988
Omnibus Trade legislation conference, bipartisanship, leadership and tough
choices occur because the congressional context dominates. To make this point
let us first consider the similarity of the three cases and then examine how
existing evidence supports the influence of the congressional context on the
conference results.
The conference of the 1986 tax
reform appears remarkable at first glance for several reasons. The legislation
coming out of conference was such a complete rewrite of previous tax law that
virtually none of previous tax provisions remained unchanged. Many tax
loopholes had been removed, and the preferences that remained were, for the
most part, narrowly defined. The new tax code lowered rates for the middle
class while remaining, at least on paper, revenue neutral. If the results are
intriguing, contemplatin of the situation at the conference opening makes them
almost amazing. The House and Senate delegations were not only separated by
chamber, but their party majorities were also in opposition. In general big
money lobbyists opposed the bill. The differences between the chambers' bills
were wide. The major conference problems included setting the top tax rate;
figuring out how to stagger it while remaining revenue neutral; and defining
the middle class. The bill needed to be done before the upcoming August recess,
and time was running short.
Despite all the difficulties the
conference encountered, it produced a bill. Conferees managed the situation by
giving unprecedented authority to two leaders, Senator Bob Packwood (R-Oe), and
Representative Dan Rostenkowski (D-II). The package the two men finally
presented, while pleasing no legislator wholly, was generally well-supported
and even hailed by Secretary of Treasury James A. Baker III as…a remarkable
bipartisan achievement.
The conference on the FY 1988
deficit reduction bill also demonstrated tough choices, bipartisanship, and
strong leaderhip. The legislation produced by the conference made tax increases
and appropriations cuts necessary to bring the budget deficit in 1988 and 1989
in line with the agreement made between Congress and the Administration at the
November 1987 budget summit. It did so successfully enough to allow Congress to
pass its appropriations bills on time for the first time in several years in
1988. What is more significant is that the conference made law a budget
agreement labelled "Republican" by Democrats hostile to their lame
duck president, and called "unconstitutional" by some legislators. If
House/Senate differences were wide in the 1986 tax conference, they may have
appeared irreconcilable in the deficit-reduction conference. The House bill had
come to the floor before the summit agreement changed the drift of fiscal
policy. The Senate bill, passed after the agreement, took the policy changes
into account. The House refused to rewrite its legislation, and tax increases
and program cuts were left in the hands of the conferees. Time was even more of
a factor than it had been in the case of the tax conference. The government was
already operating under Gramm-Rudman-Hollings sequestration. If appropriations
and reconciliation legislation was not passed soon; it would have to shut down
completely.
As in the case of the tax reform,
the conference came through. Big problems, such as tax increases, program cuts
and Reagans's demands, were resolved by private meetings between powerful
committee leaders and the chamber leadership. In the end, although the
majorities of both houses were Democratic, some characteristically Republican
preferences made their way into the bill. The Fairness Doctrine was removed and
aid for the Contras was included in a bid to avoid presidential veto.
The conferences on the 1988 Omnibus
Trade Bill was similar in character to the tax reform and reconciliation
conferences already described. The bill managed to create a comprehensive trade
program putting in the president's hands the authority and responsibility to
react to other nations' unfair trade practices despite the fact that the
Administration preferred not to have a bill at all. The bipartisan agreement on
the major tenets of the legislation was strong enough that even though the
president vetoed the first version of the bill, he was forced to allow all but
a few relatively minor provisions of the bill become law. Even the plant
closing provision became law, although it wsa separated from the rest of the
bill by a self-executing rule.
The three conference considered are
characterized by bipartisanship, leadership and tough choices. It is possible
this characterization came about as a sort of legislative miracle. But it is
more likely the operating principle in the three cases is the congressional
context.
The trade bill conference used
strong leadership to make tough choices as did the tax reform and
reconciliation conferences. Since revenue-neutrality was not a concern of trade
legislation, the conference could have been more tempted to practice
distribution than either the tax or deficit-reduction conferences. But the
conferees did not produce a work of protectionism to benefit industries in the
states they represented. The Washington Post explained the conference
this way:
Lloyd Bentsen, Senate manager of
the bill, did a skillful piece of work, matched by his counterpart in the
House, Dn Rostenkowski. Early in the process they agreed the bill was not to be
loaded up with favours for constituents, protection for hard-luck industries or
the usual assortment of gross giveaways. Along the way a number of
protectionist horrors got voted into either the House or Senate bill but, not
entirely by accident, never in both. All but the most minor were scrubbed out
in conference, perhaps the most complex conference in congressional history.4
The congressional context implies
that conferees were more concerned with demonstrating Congress's ability to
produce cohesive policy than in gain for themselves, their committees or their
chambers. The congressional context could be expected to come into play where
ever congressional policy-making prowess is questioned. The pressure on
Congress to produce policy was great in the tax, deficit-reduction, and trade
areas.
In the case of the tax reform legislation,
Congress needed a bill to keep from looking foolish next to a president who put
tax reform high on his agenda. Republicans in the Senate would not want to come
across as unable to deliver on the party's big issues. House Democrats, on the
other hand, were probably afraid of being stuck with the hot potato if tax
reform failed to make it. This has been called the "don't let the dog die
on my doorstep" approach to lawmaking. The House supported the conference
action out of fear of political retribution from Reagan, while Senate
Republicans supported it because they worried, if they failed to produce a
bill, GOP seats would be on the line in the next elections.
The pressures to produce were also
high in the case of the FY 1988 deficit-reduction legislation. "the
deficit is now a mainstream issue. Lawmakers who once boasted of pushing
through new spending now brag as much about their cost-cutting prowess."5
If a general emphasis on fiscal restraint was not enough to spur legislators to
tough choices, the October 1987 stock market crash was. In November they
convened a budget summit with the Administration. But, as the previous
discussion of the deficit-reduction legislation has indicated, the summit alone
was not enough to get policy in order. The conference became the arena where
Congress's ability to legislate in tight circumstances was tested. As House
Majority Leader, Thomas S. Foley said, if the conference failed to write a bill
in conformance with the budget summit, Congress would give off the impression
that "nobody's in charge".
The Omnibus Trade Bill conference
was not as clearly under pressure for performance as the tax reform conference
or the reconciliation conference. Yet some pressures did exist. After the
devaluing of the dollar in the fall of 1987, the trade deficit could hardly
have been far from the public mind. The presidential bid of Representative
Richard Gephardt brought the trade issue into the campaign arena. As evidence
to the fact, conferees considered retaining the Gephardt amendment in the final
version of the trade bill although it barely passed the House and was not
included in the Senate version at all. It was not dropped from the bill until
Gephardt suffered in the Super Tuesday primaries. Beside the pressures for the
trade bill was an incentive–Congress could look strong against the president.
The president did not want a trade bill and Congress turned the moment to its
advantage, "We want to produce a product that would be attractive to the
president or that would be embarassing to him if he were to veto it," said
Rostenkowski. Although the president won the first round by proferring a veto
the Senate wsa a few votes short of overriding, Congress did get him to accept
trade legislation. In fact, in mid-conference, Senator John C. Danforth (R-Mo)
remarked "This is not a conference between the two houses. It's a
conference between Congress and the administration."6
Conclusion
Pressures and incentives from
outside Congress force it to think of itself as a single body and to do therefore
what is in its interest as a single body. Such thinking is likely to be more
prevalent in conference where legislators are working together on key bills
with the final intent of sending them to the president. This supports a
decision-making ethic that might allow for more responsible decisions. It
certainly allows for bipartisanship, leadership and tough choices as the three
cases demonstrate.
Of course, while the congressional
context allows for preconditions to responsible policy-making it does not
guarantee it. In some respects it may produce even greater road blocks to good
policy than do the individual, committee or institutional contexts. Although
the politics of distribution are insufficient for dealing with situations of
financial crisis, one at least senses that constituents are getting what they
want if not what they need. But in the decision-making process of the
congressional context one senses a great many constituents are not
"getting". Their enforced frugality may be beneficial to them in the
larger picture. Then again, it may not. Who is to say that bipartisanship
connotes an intelligent understanding of policy issues? Or that strong
leadership is always just leadership? And is a tough choice necessarily a right
choice?
These are questions that deserve
answers. But we will be unable to answer them if we continue to look at
conferences from the chambers' point of view instead of examining them on the
merit of their independent contribution to policy-making.
Notes
1. Richard F. Fenno, Jr. The
Power of the Purse: Appropriations Politics in Congress, Boston: Little,
Brown & Co., 1966, p. 661.
2. Lawrence D. Longley and Walter
J. Oleszek. "The Three Contexts of Congressional Conference Committee
Politics: Bicameral Politics Overviewed", Paper delivered at the 1983
Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago,
September 1, 1983.
3. Eileen Shanahan. "Tax
Conferees Start Work, Highlight Problems", Congressional Quarterly
Weekly Report, July 19, 1986, pp. 1599-1603.
4. Washington Post, August
5, 1988.
5. Lawrence J. Haas. "The
Deficit Culture", The National Journal, June 4, 1988, pp.
1460-1467.
6. Elizabeth Wehr.
"Negotiations on the Trade Bill Gain Momentum", Congressional
Quarterly Weekly Report, March 19, 1988, pp. 732-734.