At the time this article was
written David Kilgour was Member of Parliament for Edmonton-Strathcona. John
Kirshner was a graduate student at the University of Michigan.
Representative democracy in Canada
is so dominated by political parties that some experts believe the party
discipline exerted on most votes in our House of Commons and provincial
legislatures is the tightest in the democratic world. Defenders of our practice
argue many Canadians prefer it this way because every candidate for each party
can be safely assumed at election time to have identical views on every issue.
Others contend our executive democracy, patterned on a system prevailing in
Great Britain three centuries ago, requires iron party discipline if our fused
legislative and executive branches of government are to function effectively.
Another reason, probably the most important, is that the practice makes life
easier for the various party leaders.
Unlike parliamentary systems in
places such as Great Britain and Australia, virtually every vote in Canadian
legislatures is considered potentially one of non-confidence in a government.
Even a frivolous opposition motion to adjourn for the day can be deemed by a
cabinet, if lost, to have been one of non-confidence. The whips of government
parties use the possibility of a premature election to browbeat their members
into becoming little more than obedient voting robots. The opposition mind-set
is so similar that we have the recent spectacle of both opposition parties
arguing that a free vote on an abortion resolution would `rip out the heart' of
our parliamentary system of government. The constituents of both provincial and
federal legislators will be the real winners if party discipline is loosened.
Private members from both government and opposition benches could then take
positions on government bills and other matters based on pleasing their
constituents instead of their respective party hierarchies.
A key recommendation of the
all-party McGrath report on parliamentary reform clearly favoured more free
votes by calling for the inclusion in any opposition motion intended to bring
down a government an explicit provision that its passage would constitute a vote
of non-confidence. Another solution to excessive party discipline is the
"positive non-confidence rule" used in the West German Bundestag. It
prescribes that an administration is only defeated if a successful opposition
non-confidence motion also names a new chancellor. For example, in the case of
the defeat of the minority Clark government in 1979 on its budget, the West
German rule would have left Clark in office unless the Liberals, New Democrats
and Social Credit MPs had agreed simultaneously on a new prime minister who
could hold the confidence of a majority of MPs.
A study of the Thirty-Second
Assembly of Ontario (1981-1985) indicated that legislators voted in uniform
party blocs about 95 percent of the time. The same basic pattern applies in the
present and at least the previous two Parliaments in Ottawa. The experience
suggests the various party leaders could just as well cast a proxy on behalf of
all their followers without bothering to have them physically present for
votes. It also overlooks that a majority or even minority government can
function effectively without such levels of party solidarity.
In the American Congress, where
admittedly there is a strict separation of powers between the executive and
legislative branches of government, legislation does get passed with far less
party loyalty. So different are the practices here in our two countries that
The Congressional Quarterly defines party unity votes as ones in which at least
51 percent of members of one party vote against 51 percent of the other party.
Under this definition, itself astonishing to Canadian legislators, the
Quarterly notes that for the years 1975-1982 party unity votes occurred in only
44.2 percent of 4,417 recorded Senate votes and in only 39.8 percent of ones in
the House of Representatives. This sample, moreover, includes the years
1976-1980 when the Democrats controlled the White House and both branches of
Congress.
A consequence of the American
practice of voting one's constituents' presumed interests first is the long-time
legislative coalition of Southern Democrats and Republicans. During 1981-82,
the "boll-weevil" era, this coalition was successful more than 85% of
the time because American legislators of both parties has a number of areas of
agreement. Whether one agreed with them or not is quite irrelevant; the point
is that Canadian bloc voting makes bi-partisan or tri-partisan agreement on
anything exceedingly rare.
If party discipline in Canada were
relaxed, it would be easier for, say, western MPs to defy their three party
establishments, if need be, in support of western issues. Coalitions composed
of members of all parties could exist for the purpose of working together on
issues of common regional or other concerns. The present adversarial attitudes
and structures of Parliament or legislatures in which opposition parties oppose
virtually anything a government proposes might well change in the direction of
parties working together for the common good.
Following redistribution this
summer, each Member of Parliament will represent on average of about 87,000
voters. At present, few government and opposition MPs have any real opportunity
to put their constituents first in votes in the House of Commons. Real power is
concentrated in the hands of the three party leaderships. Canadian democracy
itself would benefit if we put our present mind-numbing party discipline where
it belongs -- in the history books.