At the time this article was written J. R.
Mallory was Emeritus Professor of Political Science at McGill University. He
was the keynote speaker at the second Commonwealth Conference on Delegated
Legislation held in Ottawa in April 1983.
One of the most basic parts of our
constitutional system is what the great English constitutional lawyer A.V.
Dicey called "the rule of law". By that Dicey meant that no man can
be punished save for a specific breach of the law and that all men from the
highest to the lowest are subject to the ordinary courts of the land. The
growth of regulatory bodies and administrative tribunals has eroded some of the
effect of his second proposition, but it is still true that the courts have
great power and authority in keeping regulatory bodies within the law and
beholden to the principles of natural justice. The trouble is that, while
courts interpret the law, they do not make it, so that legislatures and the
subordinate bodies to whom they give regulatory powers are able to make laws
and regulations that offend against our notions of natural justice. It is hard
for the courts to prevent this from happening, even when there are Charters of
Rights enshrined in the constitution.
Under a system of parliamentary sovereignty
(even if partially limited by a Charter of Rights as it is in Canada) there is
only limited constitutional protection of the rule of law and of the principles
of natural justice. The ultimate safeguard of these principles in the end is
the conscience of the legislature. How far have the values of constitutionalism
been internalized in the minds of ministers and parliamentarians? How far can
parliament as an institution protect these values against governments who may
be tempted to ignore them?
The Role of Parliament in Controlling the
Executive
Nearly twenty years ago Professor Bernard
Crick, in his influential and perceptive Reform of Parliament, wrote:
Thus the phrase 'Parliamentary control'. and
talk about the 'decline of Parliamentary control', should not mislead anyone
into asking for a situation in which governments can have their legislation
changed or defeated, or their life terminated ... Control means influence, not
direct power; advice not command; criticism, not obstruction; scrutiny, not
initiation; and publicity, not secrecy.1
We must, in short, be realistic about the
role of Parliament in the Westminster system. The government has been chosen to
govern: the opposition is a "government in waiting", using its
resources including what goes on in Parliament as a part of what Professor
Crick has called "a permanent election campaign" which begins with
the summoning of a new Parliament and continues until it is dissolved and the
real election campaign begins. Everything that goes on in Parliament is a
contest between organized groups of politicians seeking a political end the
control of the government.
A legislative chamber is made up of a large
number of persons ostensibly engaged in the public ventilation of great issues
for the edification of the electorate. Much of the time they are in fact merely
legitimating coherent legislative proposals which have already reached mature
and final form within the machinery of the executive. Where there are
disciplined political parties and majority governments there is little that can
be done to modify legislative proposals. The debate in a parliamentary chamber
takes place within a complex framework of rules which allow discussion to take
place, but which are also designed to facilitate the progress of legislation. A
determined opposition can cause so much delay that many measures perforce die
on the order paper, but the ones that the government is determined to pass will
survive, In the minds of both government and opposition the object of the whole
exercise is to lay the groundwork for the next election. Parliamentary debate is
not legislation in the ordinary sense of the term, but simply legitimation.
Since it is difficult for a large body of
persons to conduct effective business, much of the activity in a parliamentary
body takes place in committees. Part of this committee work is concerned with
stages of the legislative process, and does not concern the present discussion.
Other parts of it relate to the functions of scrutiny and control. All
committees have some characteristics in common. They can be more businesslike
because of their small size, and the specialized nature of their tasks makes
their members more knowledgeable and capable of becoming more effective. They
also have one characteristic which makes them somewhat different from their
parent body, where ardent political partisans engage in daily combat over
political advantage. As small groups committees are susceptible to what is
known as small group behaviour a tendency towards a corporate identity of their
own which softens the adversary character of life in a parliamentary chamber.
For this reason they tend to be somewhat distrusted by party managers. A member
who devotes the major part of his time to committee work may also risk his
political career if he seriously neglects more highly visible political work on
the floor of the House and in his constituency. As a consequence there are
never enough members available to become expert committee men.
Governments, which control the way in which a
legislative chamber does its business, have been reluctant in our system to
give too much power to committees on the ground that this will undermine the
proper constitutional relationship between the cabinet and Parliament. This is
one of the reasons why recent generosity in Canada in increasing the office and
research facilities of members and party caucuses has not been extended to
enhancing committee staffs. Nevertheless. there are some kinds of surveillance
and scrutiny which can be done only if committees have adequate and expert
staffs under their own control.2
The Scrutiny of Statutory Instruments
The growth of the reach of the modern state
has made it unavoidable that legislatures – hard-pressed for time – should pass
many laws in skeletal form, leaving ministers or regulatory agencies the task
of framing regulations to achieve the specific purpose of the law. Such matters
as safety in the air or in the marketing of drugs require frequent modification
in the rules as a result of rapid technological change. It would be absurd to
expect each new problem to lead to the full and solemn process of statutory
amendment.
The shift from statutory to executive
regulation was first perceived during the First World War. It did not decline
with the coming of peace. In Great Britain the phenomenon was denounced by Lord
Hewart in The New Despotism, examined by the Committee on Ministers' Powers in
1932, and more fully discussed by Sir Carleton Alien in 1945.3
Concern in Canada was expressed by Brooke Claxton in a Commons debate in 1943.
Subsequently Parliament in 1950 passed the Regulations Act, followed some
twenty years later by the Statutory Instruments Act in 1971, and the setting up
of a scrutiny committee of both Houses in the following year.4
It is obviously impossible to return to the
halcyon days of the night watchman state when Parliament had plenty of time to
discuss every change in the law, no matter how minute. But how, without
paralyzing the whole legislative process, is parliamentary control to be asserted?
In the first place it should be possible to distinguish as the Committee on
Ministers' Powers did between a reasonable use of the regulatory power by the
executive and a use which creates dangers to the basic constitutional values of
the state. When ministers possess the power to raise taxes or to amend acts of
Parliament by executive order the "decline of Parliament" is
dramatically illustrated. Orders which make novel and unusual use of statutory
power or trespass unduly on the liberty of the subject are the sort of grave
issues which should be restricted to the normal legislative process in
Parliament. And yet such orders may be legal, and therefore not subject to
control by the courts.
A second issue is whether scrutiny of
questionable orders should deal essentially with form, or should it extend to
substance and policy. In this case a legislative committee can be accused of
reviving policy issues which Parliament has already settled in the parent
legislation. Nevertheless, regulations do sometimes seem to go beyond what
Parliament appears to have intended and there should be some parliamentary
means of reopening the issue. A normal parliamentary scrutiny committee, which
has built up knowledge and experience in dealing with form rather than the substance
of delegated legislation. may not be the best forum to deal with such issues.
It might be desirable to divide the business of scrutiny between two different
parliamentary bodies those that are experts in clarity and those that deal with
the subject matter of policy. How these two operations can be made to function
in tandem has been the subject of several recommendations recently in Canada.
Recent Canadian Proposals
One of the most important aspects of a
general procedural reform in the Commons tabled in 1979 was an improved method
of dealing with statutory instruments.5 At about the same time the
Standing Joint Committee of the Senate and House of Commons on Regulations and
Other Statutory Instruments was preparing a report aimed at improving its capacity
to carry out its mandate,6 and a Senate Committee in 1980 also made
useful suggestions for improving the scrutiny of delegated legislation.7
I shall consider each of them in turn.
Shortly before the end of its brief life,
the Progressive Conservative government tabled in the House of Commons, on
November 23, 1979, a number of proposals which had been foreshadowed in the
Speech from the Throne "to extend the power of Parliament ... to
strengthen the powers and resources of parliamentary committees . . ." to
provide more opportunity for initiatives by private members, and generally to
make ministers more accountable. These included greater opportunities to
discuss committee reports (it should be noted that several of the reports of
the Statutory Instruments Committee have been discussed in the Senate but
hardly ever in the Commons, presumably because of the reluctance of the
government to afford time). There was also a proposal that standing orders be
revised to increase opportunities for affirmative or negative resolutions on
delegated legislation, a requirement which is comparatively rare in Canada.
Another useful proposal was that the enabling clauses of bills be
simultaneously referred to the Statutory Instruments Committee and to the
relevant standing committee after second reading.
A large number of dubious regulations are a
consequence of the tendency of past parliaments to pass broad and ambiguous
delegation clauses. If more attention were paid to delegation clauses before
laws are passed, the work of the Statutory Instruments Committee would be
progressively eased. For while it is sometimes possible to persuade an agency
to modify or withdraw an offending regulation, it is impossible to expect that
parliamentary time will be found to make amendments to existing laws in order
to strengthen parliamentary control of the executive.
The general thrust of the Conservative
proposals was to increase the power of the ordinary members and to loosen the
government's control over committees. It is not without significance that these
proposals were made by a new government whose party had been out of office for
fifteen years. As Gerald Baldwin once remarked about freedom of information
legislation, the only time to get it is before a government has been in power long
enough to be afraid of it. It is therefore not surprising that none of the
proposed reforms were taken up by the Liberals when they returned to power.
Their own priorities for parliamentary reform were concerned with improving the
efficiency of the legislative process, and not with making life easier for
critics of the government.
The Joint Standing Committee on Regulations
and other Statutory Instruments in its 1980 Report made an eloquent plea for
confining government to "the stern restraint of the rule of law, and the
control of arbitrary if well-meaning acts" through more effective
parliamentary control. At the time that the report came out, the occasion
seemed unusually propitious with the "deregulation debate" then at
its height, in both Canada and the United States. The question has also become
a fashionable one with economists, and has engaged the attention of the
Economic Council of Canada, as well as of a parliamentary task force in the
Commons, and has led to the designation of a senior minister of the Crown to
take the matter in hand. While much, if not all of the deregulation debate has
been concerned with policy issues how much regulation and of what kind, and its
effect on costs and services to the public it seemed a good time to return to the
question of "how" as well as "why".
In its report the Committee thought it had
found a solution to the problem of how to reform old laws which had been too
generous and vague in their grant of delegated legislative power through the
use of "amending Bills introduced in the Senate upon the recommendation of
the Regulatory Review Committee and subject to all-party agreement." They
also proposed to strengthen the process of parliamentary control by providing
that all subordinate legislation not already subject to a statutory affirmative
procedure should be subject to disallowance by resolution of either House and
that the executive be barred from remaking any statutory instrument so
disallowed for a period of six months from its disallowance. This proposal was
also endorsed by the Senate Committee on Justice and Legal Affairs. Such a
power might have some deterrent effect, but, unless there is a remarkable
change in the relationships between government and Parliament, it is difficult
to see a disallowance resolution being carried. If this happened in the Commons
it would show that the government whips had lost effective control over their
own members. If it happened in the Senate it might be the incident that finally
gave momentum to radical changes in that body. Accordingly even an opposition
majority in the Senate might think twice about it.
A more promising proposal was one that would
enlarge the scope of prior notification and consultative procedures. This
recommendation may in part have stemmed from a fear of giving too much power to
committees reviewing the merit of proposed regulations. They said
"committees conducting such reviews would need to guard against the danger
of their scrutiny of policy being too much influenced by their expert staff who
might be simply endeavouring to have their own personal judgments substituted
for those of servants of the Crown to whom Parliament had originally delegated
subordinate law making authority." This is no doubt an argument which
governments will be happy to deploy again and again against the granting of
power to any committee that they cannot control. The Joint Committee may have
yielded to considerations of political prudence in their self-conscious role as
guardians of constitutional propriety. However, notification and consultation
pose no such dangers to the pure values of the constitution: "More
effective than any scheme of parliamentary scrutiny of the policy of a proposed
subordinate law that can now be devised is an obligation to make the proposed
law public, to state the reasons for its making and to consider representations
from the public, whether individuals or groups." To a considerable extent
recent regulations by the Treasury Board are now requiring greater use of
notification and comment procedures. How far these procedures will inoculate us
against the abuses of the regulatory state remain to be seen.
Regulatory Control: How Much Progress?
Parliaments in various countries which operate
under the Westminster system have been trying in various ways to act as
watchdogs on the executive while ministers have more and more displaced
Parliament as the source of legislation. This counter offensive to curb the
growing legislative power of the executive has been going on for more than
sixty years. How much has it accomplished? How much can it accomplish?
Among the obstacles I would place first an
unrealistic appreciation of the situation. No matter how much we may yearn for
it I doubt that we will get very far in getting the government off our backs
and returning to the golden age of laissez-faire. The urge for deregulation may
rid us of a few rules that are no longer in accord with contemporary standards
after all we have gotten rid of prohibition and censorship is declining. But
other kinds of regulation will be difficult to resist. A higher level of
environmental standards is more than a matter of aesthetics – it is becoming a
matter of the air we need to breathe and the water we need to drink. Canadian
history is full of examples of partnerships between the state and the private
sector which have created a strong built-in tolerance for state regulation in
our political culture. A consequence of this is that it is difficult to
persuade people that the regulatory process, which experience has taught us is
good, is in need of watching. The notion that we have to regulate the
regulators is just that extra bit of political sophistication that is not easy
to inculcate.
The current wave of enthusiasm for
deregulation is based on a very different perception of issues than that of
parliamentary control of the regulatory process. Much of the sentiment for
deregulation is based on nineteenth century liberal economics. It is not easy
for its proponents to see the issue of constitutional values. There is not a
large attentive public for a discussion of the techniques for controlling
arbitrary power in a constitutional order. In addition to the difficulty of
being heard, the advocates of more refined parliamentary control over the
executive have to contend with other obstacles which are inherent in the
Westminster system.
The system of cabinet government which we
have is based on the notion that it is the business of governments to govern,
and that Parliament must not seek to usurp the role of government. The American
separation of powers which enables congressional committees to be something
like parallel governments is utterly different from our own system, and
Canadian politicians in office will continue to resist the granting of powers
or facilities which would make parliamentary committees in any sense
independent arms of government. Hence the suggestion that a scrutiny committee
might have the power to annul an order has been resisted on grounds of outraged
constitutionalism. and even the employment of annulment orders by either house
is not an idea which governments are likely to encourage. It implies a
loosening of caucus discipline in the House which is anathema to party
managers. Accordingly any modest success which a scrutiny committee achieves
essentially through the ability to persuade rather than the power to veto is
achieved in a climate of chill hostility.
A second factor. which is not peculiar to
the Westminster system, is that of excess of bureaucratic zeal. Civil servants
are the prime initiators of program proposals. and even when the program
originates with ministers (as is sometimes the case) it is the civil servants
who work out the details of program implementation " Naturally they prefer
regulations which will simplify administration and achieve ' program objectives
in the most direct way. In drafting such regulations they and their legal
advisers will push whatever statutory powers they have to the limit and
occasionally hope to go beyond what is either lawful or acceptable. The checks
on bureaucratic excess within the cabinet system in Canada seems to be
perfunctory at best. so that a legislative scrutiny committee is the only
check.
If Canadian experience tells us anything. it
is that one of the most difficult questions is whether a proposed regulation is
legal or not. The department – often backed by the Department of Justice – says
that it is: the scrutiny committee is convinced that it is not. The committee
is not a court and has no legal power, so that the department has a good chance
of getting its way. Only when some aggrieved party challenges the regulation in
court can its legality be authoritatively determined and the challenge may go
all the way to the Supreme Court of Canada at great expense of time and
treasure to the aggrieved appellant.
One of the objects of the scrutiny process
is to provide an alternative to expensive litigation in those cases, which are
fairly numerous, where there is legitimate doubt whether a regulation is intra
vires. In the end this can be determined authoritatively only by judges, whose
duty is to uphold the law and the constitution. Politicians are not judges,
they are political men. Their motives cannot be dissociated from considerations
of political advantage, for that is what the political system is all about.
However, whether they are scrutinizing the public accounts or the regulatory
process. they cannot divorce themselves from their political role. Decent and
honest men will tend to be even-handed but they cannot be blamed if the
prospect of political advantage adds to their zeal. Elected politicians need to
be partisans and the need to be involved in activities which are politically
rewarding and politically visible. Much scrutiny activity does not have these
qualities, so that it will be hard to recruit and retain the kind of members a
strong scrutiny committee needs. To a degree this difficulty is mitigated when
scrutiny committees involve members of a second chamber which is either
appointed or elected for a comparatively long term. Nevertheless, the
difficulty remains in combining a quasi judicial role (and a role as moral
censor of constitutional values) with the requirements of the political
process. In the unending antagonistic relations between governments aiming to
realize their own goals and scrutiny committees seeking a more open and
responsive regulatory process, the balance will remain tilted towards
governments.
Notes
1. Bernard Crick, The Reform of
Parliament, Second Edition, London, 1968, p. 80.
2. There are of course difficulties, which
should not be overlooked, in inflating the size and role of committee staffs.
See J.R. Mallory, "Parliament in the Eighties", in R. Kenneth Carty
and W. Peter Ward (eds.) Entering the Eighties: Canada in Crisis,
Toronto, 1980.
3. Lord Hewart, The New Despotism,
London, 1929, Report of the Committee on Ministers' Powers, Cmd. 4060, C.K.
Allen, Law and Orders, London, 1945,; John E. Kersell, Parliamentary
Supervision of Delegated Legislation, London, 1960.
4. For a summary of these developments see
J.R. Mallory, "Curtailing 'Divine Right': the Control of Delegated
Legislation in Canada" in O.P. Dwivedi (ed.) The Administrative State
in Canada, Toronto, 1982, pp. 131-49.
5. For a general review of the proposals see
Parliamentary Government, 1:2 pp. 12-15.
6. Joint Standing Committee on Regulations
and Other Statutory Instruments, First Report to the Thirty-Second
Parliament, Tabled June 3, 1980.
7. Standing Senate Committee on Justice and
Legal Affairs, Report on Certain Aspects of the Canadian Constitution,
November 1980.