PDF
Guy Tremblay
This article suggests that
despite a significant evolution in society over recent decades the basic
function of legislators remains largely the same. It then considers whether
these functions are likely to change in the years ahead.
In 1965 Jean Charles Bonenfant wrote about the evolution of
the legislator’s role 1 and I believe that the role of members has
remained essentially the same to the present.
Academics have broken down
this role in various ways. For example, it has been said of members that they
perform “five major distinct roles: these are to perform a representational,
legislative, monitoring, advocacy and trusteeship role in the national public
interest.” 2 I will rather break these roles down into a more
simple and classical version, which highlights three major functions: members
are legislators, perform a government monitoring or watchdog function and
defend the interests of their constituents. In the title of one of his columns,
Mr Bonenfant used the terms legislative, monitoring and intermediary
functions. The first two functions are performed collectively, in the National
Assembly and on its committees; the third function is performed individually by
each MNA. Each of these three functions has evolved markedly since the middle
of the 20th century.
Overview of Evolution to Date
The National Assembly passes a
great deal more legislation now than it did in the middle of the last century.
Government regulations have likewise proliferated. State intervention has also
increased in every facet of life in society. In other words, the collective or
institutional dimension of the member’s role has increased considerably.
However, the basic legislative work as such, which is often highly technical,
is carried out at the public administration and government levels. The member’s
role as a legislator has therefore remained limited and very slim. At the same
time, the member’s monitoring role, or to put it another way the member’s role
as the watchdog of the executive has developed and become stronger.
But in my view, the crucial
change that has taken place in the institutional dimension of members’ work
relates to the conditions under which they perform their work. The reign of
silence imposed on members by Maurice Duplessis is long gone, and from this
standpoint at least, party discipline has lessened. Members have also gradually
achieved more independence from the government. The periodic improvements made
to the Standing Orders of the National Assembly have also made a significant
contribution. Jean-Charles Bonenfant was the chief architect of the 1971 and
1972 reform, the spirit of which was to serve the legislative rather than the
executive. At the time, changes to the rules on parliamentary committees
and the role of the Speaker of the National Assembly contributed the most to
this. For Mr Bonenfant, the salvation of parliamentarism rested with the
parliamentary committees. He wrote with some satisfaction that,
In recent years, both in
Quebec City and in Ottawa, parliamentary committees have developed in a way
that they never had in the past. There has been an increase in the number of
these committees, they have been made more functional, they have been sitting
during parliamentary recesses, and bills and budgetary matters have been the
subject of considerable discussion in these committees.3
Mr Bonenfant also pointed out
in 1973 that the new Standing Orders of the National Assembly gave the Speaker
more discretion, more authority and consequently, more independence, which is
very important; for example, the Speaker decisions in the National Assembly
could no longer be appealed.
After that, the committee
system and the Speaker’s role continued to evolve similarly. The 1984 reform
reduced the number of standing committees from 24 to 9, while increasing their
powers and their autonomy. The allocation among the parties of the Chair and
Vice-Chair positions on these committees, which is the most active role
involving these duties and mandates that each committee can select on its own
initiative, further increased the autonomy of the National Assembly. Likewise,
the role of the Speaker of the National Assembly was further strengthened in
1999 by making the position one in which the incumbent was to be elected by
secret ballot.
And what of the evolution of
the role of members of the National Assembly in terms of their individual
function, as an intermediary, or to use an expression Mr Bonenfant was
fond of, “their usual role as a broker between voters and the government”? I
believe that it has simply become consolidated. Given the relatively large
number of seats in the National Assembly and the continued existence of
less populous remote ridings, members can still act effectively as an
intermediary between constituents and the machinery of government. The tools
available to members have also been improved, though there may be variations
based on the size of the electoral district, the funds available to run a
riding office and hire staff, and to pay for travel and communications.
Future Evolution
What will happen to these
basic functions in the future? There are many different factors that can change
or even transform the role of members, and in some cases these are
hypothetical. For example, the new voting system proposed by the Steering
Committee on the Reform of Democratic Institutions, chaired by Claude
Béland, will have a definite impact on all three facets of the role of members
of the National Assembly.4 First of all, the proportional regional
representation under consideration would lead to some ridings having as many as
8 members. Because these members would be elected on the basis of
candidates’ lists, they would often have a better chance of being re-elected.
This could mean that they might take less of an interest or receive less
encouragement than they do now to perform their role as intermediaries, to take
the individual grievances of their constituents seriously, particularly as
there would be far more of them. To use another of Mr Bonenfant’s
favourite colourful expression, there is a risk that the members of the
National Assembly would no longer be “the pressure group for people who do not
have one”.
But the regional proportional
representation suggested in the Béland Report would mainly strengthen the
position of members as legislators and as government watchdogs. Unlike the
current electoral system, which has invariably led to majority governments in
Quebec since 1867, proportional representation would frequently lead to
minority or coalition governments. Parliamentarians would thus have a better
chance of passing bills or amendments that the government would otherwise not
have agreed to, and they would be in a better position to criticize the
government and exert effective control over its action. If, instead of adopting
the proportional representation advocated by the Béland Report, Quebec were to
adopt a form of a hybrid voting system, the consequences would be felt less
radically. However, I feel that the choice of a voting system ought not to
depend on how it would affect the role of the members, but rather on its
ability to reconcile democracy and government effectiveness. From this
standpoint, the ideal would be to adopt a system that is as proportional as
possible, and which would still make it possible to regularly give rise to
homogeneous majority governments. The fact remains that the traditional system
is not as bad as people say. It generates majority governments, keeps
government effective and as Georges Burdeau has explained in his classic works,
makes it possible to identify a “national will” and accurately reflects the
choices expressed by the people, and in the matter under discussion, in the
form of power that is “correctness through alternation”.5
Apart from changing the voting
system, other proposals made by the Béland Committee could have even more of an
influence on the role of Quebec members of the National Assembly. I will only
go over these briefly, because they do not appear to have the support of the
current government. The proposals in question are the holding of elections on a
fixed date, and a review of the possibility of having the Premier elected by
direct universal suffrage, and the adoption of an American-style separation of
powers. Doing this would certainly greatly strengthened the position of Quebec
members, because they would become part of an institution that would be
independent from the government. However, apart from the fact that doing so
would be clearly unconstitutional, such a reform is undesirable because it
would weaken Quebec too much. As a distinct society that is both vulnerable and
isolated in North America, Quebec would be unwise to imitate the constitutional
system adopted by our neighbours to the South, for whom the best form of
government is as little government as possible, as many writers on the subject
have pointed out.
Leaving aside any hypothetical
or virtual evolutionary factors, there is another factor already at work, one
that is properly legal and that is destined to affect the evolution of the role
of members of the National Assembly in the near future. This is section 3 of
the Canadian Charter of Rights and Freedoms, and the way it has been
interpreted by the courts. This section is very simple, and it reads as
follows: “Every citizen of Canada has the right to vote in an election of
members of the House of Commons or of a Legislative Assembly and to be qualified
for membership therein.” The right to vote and to run for office is, like all
of the other rights under the Charter, subject to limitations that the
government must, in the event of a challenge, demonstrate to be reasonable.
However, unlike most Charter rights, section 3 is not subject to a
specific exemption that is renewable every five years under section 33.
In this connection, allow me a
digression about the surprising use by the Supreme Court of this
“notwithstanding clause”, meaning section 33, which allows the federal
Parliament or any provincial Parliament an exception from sections 2 and 7 to
15 (and which does not allow an exception to sections 3 to 6 nor to section 16
ff.). In cases where a right that is subject to the exception is under consideration,
the Court sometimes allows a generous application against an Act by saying that
if Parliament disagrees, it can always have recourse to the express exception.6
Conversely, in the jurisprudence concerning section 3 (i.e. the right to
vote and to run for office), the Court has justified the severity of the
legislative options by underscoring the importance assigned by those who
drafted the Charter to the right in question by the mere fact of having
excepted it from the notwithstanding clause.7 The fact that the Canadian
Charter contains a provision that allows express derogation from certain
rights has therefore served to reinforce judicial activism, both with respect
to rights that can be excepted and rights that cannot. To this must be added another
fact: apart from Quebec, only Saskatchewan has ever made use of the
notwithstanding clause, and it did so once only, in 1986. The bottom line is
that a provision intended to give the final word to elected representatives and
limit government by the courts appears to have ended up doing the very
opposite.
The fact nevertheless remains
that in the Canadian Charter, the right to vote and to run for office
has been given and will continue to receive a broad interpretation by the
courts and the limits placed on this right by Parliament will be severely
circumscribed. With respect to what concerns us here, the jurisprudence would
promote small political parties and new political parties. Indeed, the benefits
currently enjoyed by the dominant political parties under the electoral
legislation will have to be extended to all parties, even marginal and regional
parties. This is what becomes clear in a Supreme Court decision of last 27 June
concerning the Communist Party of Canada (Figueroa). The Court
unanimously held that certain provisions of the Canada Elections Act
requiring that at least 50 candidates in 50 electoral districts be nominated to
obtain registered party status were unconstitutional. Three of the benefits to
registered parties were therefore declared unconstitutional under the Canadian
Charter because they were not allowed to the other parties. These three
benefits are the right of candidates to issue tax receipts for donations made
outside the election period, to transfer unspent election funds to the party
and to list their party affiliation on the ballot papers.
A majority of six judges gave
an individualistic interpretation to section 3 of the Canadian Charter
and expressly rejected the competing approach advocated by the three other
judges and by the Ontario Court of Appeal, which took into account collective
interests such as promoting cohesion through the major national parties or
through an aggregation of political will. According to the majority, the right
to vote and the right to run for office imply that every citizen has the right
“to play a meaningful role in the electoral process” – and this right to
participate includes a right to information. In the reasons given by these
judges, the words “every citizen” appear frequently as a leitmotiv. In
their view, the legislator cannot enhance the ability of some to participate at
the expense of others, including marginal or regional parties. And the section
3 rights cannot be made subject to limits other than those that can be
justified by evidence presented within the strict framework of section 1 of the
Charter.
The Supreme Court’s decision
in Figueroa has an impact on those benefits that were not challenged in
the case and which benefited the registered parties. These are the right to
free broadcast time, the right to purchase reserved broadcast time and the
right to partial reimbursement of election expenses upon receiving a certain
percentage of the vote. In fact, as the provisions concerning the registration
of parties that nominate at least 50 candidates were declared unconstitutional,
all the consequences of such registration, had to be thrown out with them. The
Court went on to say that no other threshold below the 50-candidate threshold
was acceptable as a reason to deny the three benefits under discussion, whereas
the judges in the minority accepted the obligation to nominate at least one and
perhaps more candidates. Bill C-51, which was introduced in the House of
Commons last month, in fact reduces the number of candidates that a party must
nominate to qualify for registration to a single candidate, which in all
likelihood will be accepted as a reasonable limit of the right under
consideration. The decision of the Supreme Court will also necessitate an
amendment to the Quebec requirement to nominate at least 20 candidates in order
for an authorized party to qualify for benefits.
The individualistic
interpretation of the right to participate in an electoral process under
section 3 of the Canadian Charter is likely to be perpetuated and to become
applied more broadly because it can be reinforced by other provisions of the
Charter, including freedom of expression, freedom of association and the right
to equality
It is worth recalling that the
Quebec Superior Court itself ruled in favour of small parties and new parties
in a case brought by Action Démocratique, which led to a revision of the Quebec
Election Act. In 1999, it ruled that the right to eligibility included:
“the right to run under identical
conditions” and it declared unconstitutional a number of financial benefits to
those parties that did best in the elections prior to the current ones, namely
to receive pay from the government, for each polling station, of two candidates
representatives, reimbursement of half the election expenses of these
candidates and an advance on this reimbursement.8
It is difficult to see why the
benefits allowed on the basis of the results of the current elections would
also not violate this “right to run as a candidate under the same conditions”.
This point of view was granted in one of the two statements of
unconstitutionality issued at trial in Figueroa, without being appealed:
this involved the provision that half of the $1,000 deposit required from a candidate
would only be repaid if that candidate obtained at least 15% of the votes.
It is therefore worth asking
if the 1994 Quebec Appeal Court decision to the effect that the repayment
provided in the Canada Elections Act of half the expenses of candidates
who obtained at least 15% of the votes is consistent with the Canadian Charter.9
(Henceforth, 60% of expenses will be repaid to candidates who received 10% of
the votes).10 Sections 457 and 457.1 of the Quebec Election Act
agree to a similar reimbursement by the government to candidates who obtained
at least 15% of the votes, as well as to political parties that receive at
least 1% of the votes cast . And the Act provides for an advance on this
reimbursement.
The financing of parties by
the government, which is covered by sections 81 ff. of the Quebec Election
Act, appears to be left vulnerable. According to these provisions, each
authorized party is entitled annually to a fraction of an amount totalling
approximately $2½ billion, proportionate to the percentage of votes
received in the last elections – with no minimum threshold established.
Analogous provisions were adopted at the federal level one week before the
Supreme Court rendered its decision in Figueroa, but these were
unfavourable to small parties and new parties: indeed, a basic number of votes
in the previous general election is required to qualify for public financing,
i.e. 2% throughout the country or 5% in electoral districts in which they
endorsed a candidate.
The “competitive” nature of
elections was noted in Figueroa, both by the minority and the majority
Supreme Court justices. The jurisprudence will therefore tend to require the
same electoral rules for everyone.
Concrete Consequences
There are concrete
consequences, but I want to eliminate two of these at the outset.
First of all, the
jurisprudence that supports marginal parties and new parties applies to the
election process but not to House business, once the election process is over.
However, this does not prevent the Canadian Charter from requiring the
legislative assemblies to officially recognize all parties represented there.
The Charter indeed applies to the legislative assemblies, but without
removing from them the privileges they need to execute their tasks.11
Now, section 3 of the Charter gives every citizen the right to
“effective representation”, meaning the right “to an effective representative”
in the Legislative Assembly. However, I do not believe that the courts will
meddle with the internal operations of the legislative assemblies to guarantee
the right to an effective representative.
Secondly, contrary to what has
been suggested in some quarters, my view is that the idea that the Canadian
Charter can render unconstitutional the current voting system ought to be
excluded. The majority justices wrote in the case dealing with the Communist
Party of Canada that the Charter is entirely neutral as to the type of
electoral system in which the right to vote or to run for office is to be
exercised. This suggests that the purpose of s. 3 is not to protect the
values or objectives that might be embedded in our current electoral system,
but, rather, to protect the right of each citizen to play a meaningful role in
the electoral process, whatever that process might be.
The fact remains that even
though the majority electoral system has not changed, Quebec (like the other
provinces and the federal government) is destined to see more parties nominate
candidates with a good chance of being elected and to see more members
representing third parties in the National Assembly. The majority voting system
that has been used in Quebec since 1867 has worked in favour of bipartism. But
it has not prevented third parties from winning occasionally, or even replacing
a traditional party, like the Conservative Party and the Union Nationale. This
gives us every reason to believe that increased diversification in the partisan
composition of the National Assembly (and the other legislative assemblies in
Canada) should result from the mandatory equalization of the ground rules
applicable both during election campaigns and outside of campaigns. This type
of diversification would lead to an evolution in the role of members of the
National Assembly. While it may from time to time generate minority governments
or governments that have smaller majorities, it will strengthen the position of
members as legislators and as government watchdogs, as we saw in connection
with the voting system. On the other hand, an increase in the number of parties
in the National Assembly would have an impact on the workload of members and on
party discipline.
When two parties are
represented by a large number of members, they can spread responsibilities,
files and functions among their members. This is more difficult for parties
that have few members. They must give up the idea of intervening in certain
areas or taking part in the proceedings of certain committees. A proliferation
of opposition parties nevertheless has an impact on the ability of the official
opposition to fully assume all of its tasks. The current situation at the House
of Commons in Ottawa is a good illustration of the problem posed by
multipartism in handling the workload. I will give as an example the work done
for six months in 2001 by the Standing Committee on Health in connection with
the draft bill on assisted human reproduction that the federal government had
introduced in the House. (This draft bill later became a bill, but it has still
not been passed by the federal Parliament). The Parliamentary Committee in question
prepared a report that reflected the position of the Liberal Party in power.
The report also included the minority report of the Canadian Alliance, which
was the official Opposition. Then, the Committee report included the dissenting
opinion of the Bloc québécois, in addition to the dissenting opinion of the New
Democratic Party, along with the dissenting opinion of MP André Bachand, the
spokesperson of the Progressive-Conservative Party. It is clear that this form
of escalation, multiplied by the number of issues to deal with, would
considerably increase the burden on members from the various opposition
parties. Even where the parties are able to cooperate, the work required to
achieve consensus would increase. Such a situation is likely to
reduce the effectiveness of the various collective roles to be performed by
members, namely their work as legislators and as government watchdogs.
Party discipline, which is
already being disputed by some people, is likely to become more flexible if
there is an increase in the number of parties with representation in the
National Assembly. Here again, various events that have occurred in the House
of Commons in recent years would tend to confirm this. The model of necessary
cohesion in two armies facing one another becomes less relevant in a multiparty
system. In addition, the members of a party that has little chance of taking
power in the short term can march in less tightly serried ranks. Nevertheless,
party discipline, if it is followed and imposed with circumspection, can be an
advantage or a benefit. It becomes really no different than the normal feelings
of loyalty between members of any social institution towards the decisions and
strategies it adopts.
It is therefore in their
legislative and government watchdog role that members will mainly have to
adjust to new conditions and evolve. Members of opposition parties in
particular may find themselves overworked and become less effective. Even
independently of the factors that may lead to an increase in the number of
parties in the National Assembly, the tools made available to members need to
be improved. Indeed, the predominance of the executive in our parliamentary
system, which is a sign both of its effectiveness and its democratic nature, is
often perceived when viewed through the other end of the opera glasses, as a
“devaluation” of the legislative function.12 All measures that can
contribute to correcting this perception, which, it must be admitted, has some
basis in reality, will be welcome. In addition to continuing to increasing the
budgets and staff made available to parties and MPs, there will be a need to
encourage the introduction and discussion of members’ bills. Furthermore, the
parliamentary committees need to be empowered under an official act to initiate
a procedure to cancel all or part of a statutory instrument, as was recently
introduced in Ottawa.13 The number of officials who, like the
Auditor General, are employed by the National Assembly and are accountable to
the National Assembly, could also be increased. And the parliamentary
committees concerned should systematically review their reports. Experience has
shown that such people are not afraid of criticizing the government, and the
Supreme Court has clearly pointed to the fact that it would be useful for them
to table their reports, even in a national assembly that is dominated by the
government party14: by criticizing the government in his report, the
officer of Parliament draws issues to the attention of the public; the
opposition in Parliament is then free to make it a subject of debate; criticism
of the government “may have an impact on how public opinion evaluates the
performance of the government”; the tabling of a report in the chamber
therefore plays “an important role” by strengthening parliamentary control over
the executive branch.
Another way of enhancing the
role of members is to make it clear that an adverse vote in the National
Assembly does not constitute a motion of non-confidence in the government,
unless the non-confidence motion was explicitly formulated as such beforehand.
A measure of this kind has been suggested on a number of occasions in recent
years. As Professor Jacques-Yvan Morin wrote:
specifying the conditions
under which a failure to reach the requisite number of votes in the House would
lead to the fall of the government would make it possible to increase the
number of opportunities for members to be free to vote in accordance with their
conscience or their individual opinion.15
Such a measure would in fact
release members from their concerns about the survival of the government (and
their own survival) in the course of the day-to-day business of the National
Assembly.
It definitely seems to me that
the application of the Canadian Charter of Rights will tend in the medium
term to strengthen a multiparty system in the National Assembly. Future reforms
of the voting system and the parliamentary system should take this new finding
into consideration to avoid unduly weakening the ability of both the
legislature and the executive branch to act. The ultimate objective of the
rules under which Quebec is organized and operates is neither to assure the
perfect expression of the people’s will, nor, on the contrary, to protect the
omnipotence of the representative agencies, whether at the executive or
legislative level. As it has been said about our parliamentary system, what we
ought to be seeking is “a democracy that does not kill democracy”, meaning that
we must succeed in reconciling collective sovereignty with the effectiveness of
the State.
Notes
1. Jean-Charles Bonenfant, “L’évolution de la
fonction parlementaire”, September 16, 1965, in Derrière les faits: les
institutions, Columns which appeared in L’Action, from 1962 to 1973,
Quebec City, 1976 (hereinafter referred to as Chroniques).
2. Jacques Bourgault, “Les rapports entre
parlementaires et fonctionnaires” in Manon Tremblay et al. (ed.), Le
parlementarisme canadien, Quebec City, P.U.L., 2000, 313, p. 315.
3. Jean-Charles Bonenfant, “Innovation dans le
droit parlementaire”, (1970) 11 Cahiers de Droit 533. See also “Le
pouvoir des commissions législatives”, 24 September 1970 and “Les commissions
parlementaires”, December 4, 1971, in Chroniques.
4. See the report of the Steering Committee on
the Reform of Democratic Institutions entitled La participation citoyenne au
cœur des institutions démocratiques québécoises, Quebec City, Government of
Quebec, March 2003, pp. 31-35.
5. Georges Burdeau, Traité de science
politique, tome V, Les régimes politiques, 3rd edition, Paris, L.G.D.J.,
1985, pp. 277-287
6. Re B.C. Motor Vehicle Act [1985] 2
S.C.R. 486, 498; Vriend v. Alberta, [1998] 1 S.C.R. 493, 565-566
and 578. See also EGALE Canada Inc. v. Canada (Attorney General),
[2003] B.C.J. No. 994 (B.C. Court of Appeal), par. 157.
7. Sauvé v. Canada (Chief Electoral
Officer), 2002 SCC 68, par. 11 and 14; Figueroa v. Canada (Attorney General),
2003 SCC 37, par. 60.
8. Hébert v. P.G. Québec, [1999]
R.J.Q. 267 (C.S.).
9. Canada (Attorney General) v. Barrette,
[1994] Q.L.R. 671 (A.C.).
10. S.C. 2003, c. 19, s. 48(1) and s. 49(2.1),
to replace sections 464(1)(b) and 465(2)(a) and (b) of the Canada Elections
Act. Registered parties are also entitled to a reimbursement of half their
election expenses if their candidates obtained at least 2% of the valid votes
or at least 5% of the votes in which votes cast in the electoral districts in
which the registered party endorsed a candidate (s. 435).
11. New Brunswick Broadcasting Co. v. Nova
Scotia (Speaker of the Legislative Assembly), [1993] 1 S.C.R. 319, House
of Commons et al. v. Vaid et al., (2002) 296 N.R. 305 (F.C.A.).
12. See for example Benoît Pelletier (ed.), Un
projet pour le Québec. Affirmation, autonomie et leadership, Final
report of the Special Committee of the Liberal Party of Quebec on the political
and constitutional future of Quebec society, October 2001, pp. 122-123 and 154.
13. Act to Amend the Statutory Instruments
Act (Disallowance Procedure for Statutory Instruments), S.C. 2003, c. 18.
This Act stemmed from a private member’s bill and not a government bill. In
1986, a disallowance procedure for statutory instruments had been established
under section 123 of the Standing Orders of the House of Commons: (2002)
25 Canadian Parliamentary Review, pp. 18-19 (Peter Bernhardt).
14. Canada (Auditor General) v. Canada
(Minister of Energy, Mines and Resources), [1989] 2 S.C.R. 49, p.104.
15. Jacques-Yvan Morin, “Une Constitution dans
un Québec souverain ou autonome”, Le Devoir, April 25, 2000, p. A7.
|