At the time this article was
written Howard Cody was Associate Professor of Political Science and Canadian
Studies at the University of Maine
Senate reform has proved a
recurring issue in Canadian federalism, including the recent ill-fated Charlottetown
constitutional accord. This article contends that most issues related to Senate
reform in Canada have been addressed in Australia. Even those which have not
can be better understood through an examination of Australian experience. The
paper is based in part on interviews with sixteen Australian Senators in May
and June 1994. All sixteen had been elected from Australia's four
"outer" states (Queensland, South Australia, Western Australia, and
Tasmania). These states, like "outer" Canada, are heavily outnumbered
in their majoritarian lower house by their two dominant neighbours (New South
Wales and Victoria). Unlike their Canadian counterparts, they enjoy equal
representation in a powerful upper house.
Australians elect their Senate on a
proportional- preferential ballot. Voting is compulsory. Each state has twelve
Senators, half of whom are elected at large from their state with the entire
House of Representatives (which also is preferential but with single-member
constituencies). Senators serve six year terms, but all Senate terms end if
there is a double dissolution of Parliament. The Senate ballot features party
boxes at the top, with party lists. The party rank-orders each of its
candidates. Voters must choose between ticking one party box and the much more
arduous rank-ordering of the candidates in order of preference. Because some
95% of Australian voters tick the party box, party executives in each of the
states enjoy great power to determine who serves in the upper chamber. By the
same token, Senators realize that their system makes them relatively anonymous
figures in their states, and they know that they will almost assuredly secure
re-election if they can satisfy state party officials with their performance in
Canberra. In other words, state party executives and not the electorate
effectively make up Australian Senators' "constituencies".
Issues for an Elected Senate
Party lists permits the Senate to
respect gender and ideological balance and to accommodate a variety of
backgrounds and careers. Although Australia's Senate shows markedly more
balance than the House of Representatives only in regard to gender, the system
does facilitate whichever representational arrangements each party chooses.
Parties, led by the governing Australian Labor Party (ALP), are moving gingerly
from the present 23% female Senate membership towards relatively equal
male-female Senate representation (but probably not through rigid quotas) by
early in the next decade. Should Canada adopt a party-list Senate, relatively
equal gender representation probably would prevail from the outset.1 Whether
provincial parties would construct party lists respecting other diversities is
less certain, but language minorities, ethnic groups, and intraparty
ideological factions might also command sufficient strength to ensure inclusion
on some party lists in some provinces.
Another possible advantage of
Australia's proportional system is that Senators can be elected from parties
which sometimes cannot secure House seats remotely proportional to their
support in a province such as Tasmanian Labor, Alberta Liberals, Quebec Tories,
Atlantic New Democrats, and most recently, Ontario Reformers. Senators from
these parties can enhance the Senate's legitimacy and reduce regionally-based
alienation amongst their parties' supporters. Moreover, proportional
representation might persuade national parties to take into account all
provinces' interests, to recognize the need to elect Senators in each province,
and to consider the views of all of their Senators. When one recalls the
difficulties of the Trudeau-era Liberals in the West, and the serious regional
tensions which these difficulties generated, one can readily understand why
Canadians might consider proportional representation for a reformed Senate.
As all Australian parties attempt
to secure seats in the House of Representatives, no party wishes to be
perceived as regional in orientation or desires its Senators to be seen as
divided on state lines. All parties, at both the Commonwealth and state levels,
recognize that national party policies must attract support in New South Wales
and Victoria. Besides, all parties in Westminster systems must show reasonable
cohesion at all times, lest they convey the damaging impression that their
leader cannot control his or her caucus. To date no Australian party has
exploited equal state representation in the Senate to establish itself
exclusively in the Senate or in one or more small states. Small state Senators
of the same party neither logroll with each other on behalf of their states'
distinctive concerns, nor do they join forces against party caucus members from
large states to press small state interests. Logrolling or other cooperation
across party lines to advance a state's concerns in meetings with ministers is
reserved for special situations, like ensuring Commonwealth subsidization of
Tasmania's ferry service.
Canada is not Australia. Canadians
surely would demand more participation in the selection of Senate candidates
than Australians do, and regionally-based parties likely would occupy many
Canadian Senate seats under any electoral system. Even so, an Australian-style
upper chamber electoral system probably would induce Canadian provincial
parties to acknowledge the national character of issues before Parliament and
develop more of a national perspective than they now display, at least in their
Senate-related responsibilities. If Canada elected Senators at large on a party
list proportional ballot, with or without a preferential component, certain
Australian features would apply there. Some Senators would share the party
affiliation of relatively few residents of their province. Most Senators almost
certainly would reflect the perspectives of their party's activists, who are
more ideological than the general population. Provincial parties might divide
into ideological factions, each one jealous of "its" inclusion or
ranking on the Senate ballot.
At-large Canadian Senators might
prove nearly as anonymous as their Australian counterparts, although broadly
inclusive nomination procedures and relaxed party discipline could lessen many
Senators' anonymity considerably. Proportionally elected Canadian Senators
might perform little casework and maintain minimal direct contact or
relationship with the public as individuals. In theory, this would free them
for other time-consuming duties, especially committee work.
If Canadians could accept a
division of labour which prevails to some extent in Canada's existing
Parliament, Senate specialization on committee work would afford MPs more time
to service their constituents.
Canadians who desire Senate reform
might seriously consider an arrangement of this nature. Thanks to casework and
other constituency obligations, Canadian and Australian MPs have little time for
committee work. This is not unusual in either country, or in Britain for that
matter, especially outside metropolitan areas. Interviews with MPs in all three
countries suggest that many MPs maintain more interest in, and more aptitude
for, constituency service than for committee responsibilities. In 1993 a New
Brunswick MP lamented, with evident frustration, that only one- third of
Canada's MPs are "committee people". One must not hold MPs wholly
responsible for this situation. Many MPs lose their enthusiasm for committee
exertions when whips order them to vote a certain way on committees and
governments routinely ignore committee reports and recommendations.
Finally on proportional
representation, Australian experience strongly suggests that it is the Senate's
electoral system and legislative power, more than equal state representation,
which account for the Senate's credibility, leverage, and distinctive
reputation. Thanks to proportional representation, it is rare for any party to
command a majority of Senate seats. Third parties (currently the Australian
Democrats and the Greens) hold the Senate balance of power when the ALP and
Liberal/National coalition (the official opposition) cannot come to terms on
legislation. On certain bills the government negotiates accommodations with the
Liberals, while on others third parties are involved. The results of these
negotiations are assessed below; the point here is that the proportional
arrangement is essential to maximize the likelihood that the Senate will operate
as an independent-minded body and not as an "echo" of the House.
Many Australians maintain that
their Parliament became genuinely bicameral only in 1949, when proportional
representation for the Senate took effect.
The Senate's unique electoral
system ensures that the upper house looks very different from the
Representatives, and guarantees that it enjoys a distinctive reputation in the
minds of Australians as a champion of small parties and as a check on
ill-considered executive policies, as well as a chamber for the small states.
Powers of the Senate
Australia's Senate enjoys
legislative powers nearly equal to the House of Representatives except that it
cannot initiate or amend money bills. In theory, the Senate can kill any
legislation, but a prolonged deadlock between the two Houses can permit the
government to request a double dissolution (forcing all Senators to face
election along with all MPs) followed by a joint sitting on the disputed
legislation. As Australia's constitutionally-imposed "nexus" mandates
a 2:1 House-Senate ratio, and as proportional representation results in an
almost evenly divided Senate with no party enjoying a majority, a joint sitting
almost always favours the House of Representatives. Thus, it is usually in the
Senate's interests to negotiate a compromise with the government on bills where
the chambers disagree. The Senate generally does so, but often only after
protracted and occasionally acrimonious semi-public bargaining. The government
also has a strong incentive to avoid a double dissolution, as the proportional
representation quota system assures that the Senate will accommodate more third
party members when the full Senate is elected at the same time than in the
usual half-Senate election. Australian Senators insist that their dispute
settlement procedure avoids the gridlock, pork barrelling, and logrolling of
the United States Congress; but Australia's government bills often require more
time, and undergo more revisions, than their Canadian counterparts.
Australia's Senators assert that
their chamber performs eight useful functions, none of which can be carried out
satisfactorily by the House of Representatives. As Senators describe them,
these services are:
Scrutiny: The Senate conducts
independent scrutiny of the executive to impose accountability and to detect
misconduct and expose corruption.
Review: The Senate takes a second
look at legislation, and offers a chance to improve government bills with
amendments.2
Legitimacy: The Senate helps
residents of small states to feel adequately represented in their national
institutions.
Power: The Senate gives small
states some protection from domination by the two large states.
Innovation: The Senate serves as a
source of new ideas, usually through third parties. Major parties eventually
co-opt these ideas, sometimes reluctantly in negotiations on amendments to
government bills.
Political philosophy: Bicameralism
supplies checks and balances, which are prima facie desirable.
Pluralism: The Senate gives
representation to small parties, which shows respect for society's increasing
pluralism.
Time management: The Senate gives
its members time for committee work, for travel throughout the country
consulting with Australians through committee hearings, and for dealing with civil
servants, all without the distractions of constituency responsibilities and the
need to campaign continuously for re-election.
Australian academic and press
observers frequently contend that their Senate performs its first two functions
(scrutiny and review) quite well, largely through its committee system. Indeed,
they often claim that these functions are so important that the Senate's
existence is justified from its performance in these areas alone. This verdict
probably stems from a major component of Australia's political mentality which
resembles the United States more than Canada. Australians' nineteenth century
Whig-Liberal principles assume that politics is a corrupting activity, and
argue that people in power must be monitored and checked as closely as
possible. Many Australians consider Commonwealth and state upper chambers
appropriate and even necessary to keep governments relatively honest. They
concur with Walter Bagehot's pronouncement that "the most dangerous of all
sinister interests is that of the executive government", and they endorse
Bagehot's warning against the "formidable sinister influence" of a
single dominant assembly. In other words, strong bicameralism is essential.3
These Australians deem the perceived rampant corruption in Queensland, the only
unicameral state, as proof of the need for scrutinizing upper houses.
The Role of the Party
Australians also often argue that
tight party discipline hinders the Senate's performance of all eight functions,
especially those which endeavour to protect the small states. Party discipline
prevents small state Senators from exploiting their two-to-one numerical
superiority. Instead, it is the opposition parties which take advantage of the
Senate's formidable powers to pursue their own agendas. For this reason,
Australia's political observers often disparagingly classify the Senate as a
"party house" rather than the intended "states house".
Interviews suggest that this
verdict is somewhat exaggerated. However, it is fully understandable, given the
close control which state party elites maintain over candidate selection and
ranking on the ballot, the tight discipline which Australian parties impose on
their Senators, and the acquiescence with which Senators accept this
discipline. Senators rarely "cross the floor" on a formal vote for
any reason. They often speak out against or try to change party policy in party
rooms (caucus), and sometimes (although much less often) in public. Senators'
dissent usually serves interests associated with their state parties or their
state party factions. Only on rare occasions will Senators publicly dissent on
"conscience" issues like the Vietnam and Persian Gulf wars.
Australian interstate disputes, and
regional alienation in the form of small states' resentment of large states'
domination, command less attention than in Canada. The Senate deserves some
credit for this fact. However, these problems do persist and Australians take
them seriously. State party interests infrequently conflict directly, but they
naturally vary from state to state, especially in the business-oriented Liberal
party and its rural-based coalition partner, the Nationals. For example, mining
in Western Australia, wine in South Australia, sugar in Queensland, and sheep
farming and timber interests in Tasmania, all make claims on their state's
Senators. Sometimes small state Senators claim to have influenced their party's
policies on important issues, especially Liberals (as on aboriginal land
claims). This occurs infrequently, usually inconspicuously, and more often in
opposition than in government. In the ALP, which enforces a Leninist
"democratic centralism" on its MPs' and Senators' recorded votes,
small state Senators exercise limited and all but invisible policy making
leverage in their caucus.
In Australia, government ministries
always include several Senators. Australian experience suggests that Senators
should be excluded from the cabinet. There would be several advantages to this practice.
It would make the Senate less likely to replicate the Commons' partisan and
adversarial atmosphere, unlike Australia where the Senate features the
"same debates, same speeches, same Question Time" as the
Representatives. Canada's government and opposition based in the Commons would
be more likely to offer Senators a degree of independence if the Senate were
separated from the cabinet. Most Senators would not aspire to a cabinet post as
their career goal. Instead, they would have to content themselves with seeking
the best positions available in the Senate, like the committee chairs. The most
ambitious Senators would perceive committee chairs as desirable power centres
which provide checks to and scrutiny over the executive as well as legislative initiative
and review.
A new Canadian Senate might become
a major player in Ottawa through its committees. Senate committees would
require relatively loose party discipline for collegial operation and public
credibility, and chairs could be rotated amongst the parties. (Australia
implemented rotation of Senate committee chairs in August 1994.) These features
would clearly differentiate the Senate from the Commons in the perceptions of
the media and the public as well as the cabinet.
The committee system of a new
Canadian Senate is crucial. Because strong party discipline makes it tempting —
and politically advisable — to follow party policy and whips' instructions,
Australian Senators often do not study issues closely or work hard in
committees. In a new Canadian Senate, Senators may need an incentive to develop
expertise in some field and to work diligently and collegially in their
committee assignments. If Senators are freed from close party control and heavy
constituency obligations, and if they perceive that their committee activity is
rewarded with real influence over policy, they are likelier to commit
themselves to committee work. Ideally, "committee people" will be
attracted to a Senate career, as now apparently happens with certain Australian
Senators.
Even more important, the Senate and
its committees will prove effective only if they possess the power to make the
government pay them respect and attention. The Australian interviews made it
absolutely clear that Australia's Senate could perform none of its eight
functions satisfactorily if it lacked credible legislative power. As a
long-serving Tasmanian Senator put it, the government cooperates with Senate
scrutiny activities, and extends consideration to Senate-initiated legislation
and amendments, only because it knows that the Senate can scuttle its bills.
Besides, unless a new Canadian Senate conspicuously exercises credible
legislative power, a Senate career, and Senate committees and their chairs,
will hold no attraction for ambitious and talented Canadians.
Because the cabinet represents the
locus of federal policy making in Canada, disqualifying Senators from the
cabinet would represent a major concession on the part of Senate reform
proponents. However, if this rule could facilitate a relatively nonpartisan and
collegial atmosphere, it might permit the Senate to exercise additional powers.
For example, if Senators could operate in a nonpartisan manner, the new chamber
could be assigned ratification functions which might enhance the perceived legitimacy
of national institutions. Specifically, Canada's Senate could be authorized to
ratify appointments to key federal boards, commissions, and corporations (the
Wheat Board, the CRTC, and the CBC come to mind, amongst others), and perhaps
even Federal and Supreme Court appointments. The Australian Senate enjoys no
ratification powers; with its partisan nature this is just as well.
Representation Issues
Canada's Triple E Senate proponents
have presented equal representation per province as a crucial symbol of the
notion that all ten of Canada's provinces enjoy an equal constitutional status.
As Canada's constitution and many federal-provincial programmes treat the
provinces differently, this argument for provincial equality lacks credibility.
Moreover, absolute provincial equality is not necessary for the Senate to
fulfil the objectives which the Canada West Foundation has identified:
"The purpose of the Senate is to offset the majoritarian implications of
the House of Commons, to offer the residents of the smaller provinces some
assurance that they cannot be casually sacrificed to the narrower interests of
the larger provinces."4 Even a formula providing modified representation
by population would supply "outer" Canada with a large majority of
Senators.
Triple E proponents might
acknowledge that their country's long-entrenched majoritarian and unicameral
mentality, which has been relatively untouched by Bagehot-style Liberalism and
pervades the provinces as well as Ottawa, undermines the principle of equal
provincial representation and complicates efforts to secure a powerful elected
Senate. The Charlottetown Senate experience suggests that Ontario and Quebec
will permit equal provincial representation only at the expense of real
legislative power for an upper house. When they were informed of the
Charlottetown Senate's powers, Australian Senators doubted that smaller
provinces could derive much benefit from this chamber. Some indicated that they
would consider a career in the Charlottetown Senate a waste of time, and that
they would instead offer for the lower house in such a Parliament. When asked
whether they considered their Senate's legislative power or its equal
representation more important for their states, nearly all respondents
concluded that only credible legislative power was indispensable. They added,
however, that the small states do require a majority of Senate seats in order
to derive much benefit from the chamber.
Australia's Senate operates
officially as a "states" house in representational terms, but current
political realities compel Canada's upper house to chart a somewhat different
course. For example, a new Canadian Senate could accommodate several aboriginal
members elected from specially devised constituencies. Public pressure likely
would induce the parties less formally to accommodate "Charter"
groups as well, especially if a proportional electoral system is adopted. A
"double majority" provision for French language and culture (as in
the Charlottetown Senate) could be included. Australia's nearly unique
preferential component confers excessive power on party elites and possibly
would prove too exotic and confusing for use in Canada.
Many Australians acknowledge that
state party executives presently exert too much control over the selection of
Senators, and that Australian voters exercise too little — indeed virtually no
— independent judgment in discriminating amongst individual Senate candidates.
If Canadians did choose to adopt a preferential ballot, the equally exotic and
confusing Tasmanian House of Assembly's Hare-Clark arrangement, in which there
is no party box and the parties offer voters no advice on how to rank-order
their selections, would be preferable to the system used for the Australian
Senate. A nexus similar to Australia's 2:1 House-Senate ratio deserves strong
support in Canada, whether or not there is a provision for a joint sitting of
the two chambers, particularly if there is no equality of provincial
representation in the Senate. Only if the Senate is relatively large compared
to the present 295 member Commons (at least 100 Senators, and 150 would be
better) could there be enough Senators from each province to represent
adequately the province's smaller parties, thereby building a reputation for
Senate legitimacy and manifesting a clear differentiation from the Commons.
Only in a relatively large Senate
could there be enough Senators in party caucuses and joint Commons-Senate
committees to advance the interests of all provinces and of those groups with
enhanced Senate representation. Finally, a comparatively large Senate is
necessary for the chamber and its members to attract notice and command public
and media attention. A small party Australian Senator insisted that there must
be as many Senators "rattling around" Parliament as possible, and
also as many of a different party complexion from House members as possible, if
the Senate can expect to make a visible contribution to the legislative
process. When Australian Senators were informed that the Charlottetown accord
Senate would have created a greater than 5:1 Commons-Senate ratio, they
speculated that Senators in such an arrangement would find themselves
"lost in the crowd" and incapable of commanding much attention and
respect — especially given their weak position in a joint sitting.
Conclusion
Early in 1994, Australian Prime
Minister Paul Keating, threatened to introduce legislation to end the Senate's
proportional representation and make the Senate match the House of
Representatives' partisan composition. In this way his or almost any government
would exercise equally total control over both Houses. Senate investigation of
government scandals and abuses of power, and Senate opposition parties' demands
for concessions before they would support government legislation, clearly had
exasperated the government. This development (which remains unresolved) shows
that Australia's Senate has been performing its scrutiny and review
responsibilities, albeit more on behalf of the opposition parties than the
small states.5 Canadians must decide for themselves whether they wish to check
— and inconvenience — their own federal executive through an upper house, and
if so, whose interests this chamber will serve.
If Canadians do desire strong
bicameralism, Australia's experience suggests that a new Senate must prove
conspicuously dissimilar to the House of Commons, with many distinctive
features which might include some unique powers. The Senate's distinctiveness
can include composition, method of election, roles and responsibilities,
committee system, cabinet eligibility, and relationships with constituents.
Canada's cabinet will treat a new Senate with respect only if the chamber
enjoys credible legislative power, yet the Senate must not become a source of
obstruction. In Australian terminology, Canada's Senate somehow must chart and
maintain a course between undesirable extremes, the "veto"
(obstruction) and the "echo" (rubber stamp). This would prove a
formidable assignment. One way to avert these polarities would involve the development
of a collegial relationship both inside the Senate and between Senators and
cabinet ministers, the adoption of a proportional electoral system, and the
imposition of a fair and decisive Commons-Senate dispute settlement mechanism.
Canadians' expectations for their
Senate differ from those of Australians. Checks and balances minded Australians
place highest priority on Senate scrutiny and review, which can be performed
(if imperfectly, and only with proportional representation) under strict party
discipline which suppresses interstate differences. Canadians assign higher
priority to legitimation and responsiveness, which lend themselves less well to
tightly disciplined parties which formulate their policies well insulated from
public attention. Canadians might note that even members of a Triple E Senate
can attract the same ridicule as their own appointed Senators. Australian
experience implies that if individual Senators and smaller provinces aspire to
exercise leverage and secure the public's respect, a legitimation and
responsiveness-oriented Canadian Senate would require election by the people,
party discipline somewhat relaxed from current practice in Australia and in
Canada's House of Commons, and Senators' visible participation in policy making.
Once again Canadians will need to strike a delicate balance. Possibly the
present British House of Commons could serve as an exemplar in regard to party
discipline. Under no circumstances should Canadian parties lose as much control
as their counterparts have in the United States. If they did so, Canada's
centrifugal tendencies likely would be exacerbated rather than alleviated. This
would create a situation in which Canada would endure some of the least
desirable features of current Canadian and United States practice at once:
legislative gridlock accompanied by heightened regional tension and alienation,
along with pervasive public disgust with legislative performance.
When Canadians next consider Senate
reform, they will have to address the Senate's committee system. Canada's House
of Commons Speaker and Standing committees currently operate much more
independently than their Australian counterparts. Even so, it is unrealistic to
expect a lower house in a Westminster system to serve as an effective scrutineer
of an executive which controls the future careers, including the chances for a
cabinet post, of the majority of most committees' members. Australians take for
granted that their lower house committee system essentially acts as an
extension of executive government. While this description would be unfair and
inaccurate in Canada, party leaders and whips impose limits to the independence
which MPs may exercise in Commons committees. These limits fall well below the
levels of independence from government control presently enjoyed by Senate
committees in Australia and Canada. If Canadians determine that an elected
Senate's committees should carry much of the responsibility for the chamber's
scrutiny, review, legitimation, and responsiveness performance and reputation,
they should consider a proportional representation chamber without cabinet
ministers.
Finally, Canada's Senate might
deviate substantially from Australian practice in respect to representation.
Proponents of Senate reform could exploit the opportunity presented by the
emergence of "Charter" Canadians to broaden the Senate appeal and
construct a more persuasive argument for strong bicameralism than they can make
on a regional basis alone. Reform proponents could emphasize the chamber's
potential to advance the interests of politically important groups not
previously associated with Senate reform, as well as the provinces and regions.
Forsaking equal provincial representation would lend credibility to their
initiative.
Notes
1. Female Australian Senators and
Canadian MPs, including government ministers, insist that gender balance does
make a difference. They argue that relatively large female representation in
Parliament makes the government direct closer attention to "women's issues"
like health, welfare, education, family matters, and social services.
2. The third-party Australian
Democrats can secure parliamentary sets only in the Senate, thanks to
proportional representation. They claim that their negotiating strength in the
Senate since 1981 has produced "well over 1000" amendments which have
helped (amongst many others) mentally and chronically ill people. farmers, and
victims of discrimination on grounds of age, disability, and sexual preference.
Senator Sid Spindler, "Keating's Bid for absolute Power", Age,
14 March 1994, p. 10.
3. Note the favourable quotations
from Bagehot in "The Senate and Responsible Government", The
Independent, June 1994, p. 8 (unsigned editorial).
4. Dr. David Elton and Dr. Peter
McCormick, "Representation in a Reformed Senate" (Calgary: Canada
West Foundation), p. 10, no date.
5. Australia's media responded
indignantly to Keating's proposals to emasculate the Senate. Opposition was
strongest in the small states. In western Australia, the West Australian
declared that the Senate provides its state with "some small protection
against the power of the central government", and that a change in voting
for the Senate would make Western Australia an "irrelevant part of the
federation". Robert Reid, "PM Challenged to Senate `Poll'", West
Australian, 5 March 1994, p. 8. The media in the other small states issued
similar statements.