At the time this article was
written Louis Massicotte was Assistant Professor in the Department of Political
Science at the University of Montreal
This article points out many of
the problems in redistributing (and possibly reducing) the number of seats in
the House of Commons. It argues that the redistribution of seats has become an
ad hoc operation in which the constitutional and legal criteria meant to guide
the whole process are modified along the way to accommodate the requirements of
the interested parties at a particular time. This has resulted, especially
since the 1960s, in significant delays between the census date and the coming
into force of the boundaries based on that census, thereby increasing the
inequalities in representation. This article is an extract from a brief
submitted to the House of Commons Standing Committee on Procedure and House
Affairs on July 6, 1994.
Not since the 1930s has a redistribution
been carried out without amending the rules in force at the time. During the
1940s, and again during the 1950s, the formula for distributing seats among the
provinces was changed. During the 1960s, the boundary procedure was changed. In
1974 and in 1985, the distribution formula was changed along the way, while at
the same time minor changes were also made in the boundary formula.
The current boundaries were
established in 1987 and are based on 1981 figures. At the time of the 1993
election, one constituency out of five exceeded the 25% variance allowed in
each province. In Ontario alone, one fourth of the ridings exceeded the allowed
variance. In Quebec, one riding in five is in the same situation. If the
electoral map is not redrawn in the meantime, these figures will undoubtedly be
even higher at the next election. According to the act, variances greater than
25% are justified only under exceptional circumstances.
The Supreme Court has rejected the
principle of absolute voter parity and opted instead for "effective"
representation. However, this principle must take into account relative voter
parity. The Court did not ask legislators to ignore the population criterion.
It said that parity of voting power, though of prime importance, was not the
only factor to be taken into account in ensuring effective representation.
"A system which dilutes one citizen's vote unduly as compared with another
citizen's vote runs the risk of providing inadequate representation to the
citizen whose vote is diluted. The legislative power of the citizen whose vote
is diluted will be reduced, as may be access to and assistance from his or her
representative. The result will be uneven and unfair representation."
Should the number of seats in the
House of Commons be capped or reduced?
The number of members has almost
been capped under the current formula. Adding six seats, based on 1991 figures,
would bring the total number to a level higher than the psychological threshold
of 300; however, this is an increase of only 2%. Based on the projections, by
the year 2016 there would be an additional increase of 17 seats in 25 years, or
less than one seat a year.
I wonder whether this modest
increase justifies replacing the current formula with yet another one, which
would be the third over three redistributions and the seventh since 1867. In
the past, we have tended to adopt new formulas to solve one particular problem
without realizing that in so doing we might be creating other problems.
In 1974, it was the loss of seats
by several provinces which prompted the abandonment of the formula which
essentially dated from 1946. We started from the assumption that a province
should not lose seats in the House of Commons even if its population was decreasing
in relative terms. The provinces were divided into three categories: small,
medium and large. Although this formula ("amalgam method") was
extremely complicated, the underlying principle was simple: the small provinces
would not lose any seats, but the big ones would be given more seats (this was
the "Quebec plus four" clause), although it meant continuous
increases in the total number of seats in the House of Commons. On the whole,
this formula resulted in a less proportional representation than the previous
one, to the detriment of Ontario and Quebec.
In short, every formula has
unpleasant consequences that are likely to be criticized. Based on the
experience of the last few decades, we should closely examine the alternatives.
Ten years later, we realized that
we had made a poor choice. We had expected an increase in Quebec's population.
In the 1981 census, Quebec's population was actually lower than predicted.
Since the formula provided for an automatic increase of four seats for Quebec,
regardless of the changes in its population, and gave Ontario a number of seats
based on Quebec is the low Quebec standard catapulted Ontario's representation
to a far higher level than had been expected. As a result in 1981 the House of
Commons was expected to have 310 seats instead of the 294 that had been
predicted seven years earlier. Statistics Canada's projections suggested
subsequent increases of about thirty seats every decade.
In 1985, inflation of parliamentary
seats became the biggest worry. The new government was concerned about the
additional costs this would entail and wanted to stabilize the growth of the
House. A decision was therefore made to start with a fixed number of seats to
be distributed (279), to which would be added a sufficient number of seats so
that no province would have fewer members than senators and would not lose
ground in relation to its 1986 representation. Representation became slightly
less proportional than it was under the amalgam system, notably because the
grandfather clause applied in relation to a lower total number of seats.
Naturally, it is the provinces with the fastest growing populations who lose
out under this "electoral equalization," to the benefit of the
provinces whose populations are decreasing.
Skepticism regarding the existence
of any truly superior alternatives is reinforced when one looks at the formula
being proposed by the Royal Commission on Electoral Reform. After having
considered this issue the Commission was unable to come up with a better
formula than one that would in the immediate future result in a House of 308
seats - 13 more than it has now - with this number increasing to 319 in 2001,
332 in 2011 and 339 in 2016. If the population of Quebec does not increase as
fast in the future as Statistics Canada has currently forecast, as occurred in
1981, then the total number of members will be even higher. If our concern is
to cap or to reduce the total number of members, then this formula does not
appear very attractive.
The Lortie formula would have the
added disadvantage of not treating equally all provinces whose populations are
decreasing. Some would keep all their seats thanks to the senatorial floor
clause, others would lose at most one seat at every redistribution, and Quebec,
as the pivotal province, would be frozen at 75 seats. Quebec and Manitoba would
become the only provinces with decreasing populations to be underrepresented.
The current formula, because of the senatorial and grandfather clauses, has the
advantage of treating all provinces with decreasing populations equally; no
provinces would lose seats and all will be slightly overrepresented.
The Lortie Commission, reflecting
the views of a number of academics, criticized the current formula for
undermining proportional representation. This stems from three provisions in
the formula:
First the territories are entitled
by law to three seats, although their total population would justify only one.
Second, the senatorial clause, at
present, allow Prince Edward Island and New Brunswick to keep as many members
as senators. This clause is virtually untouchable, since the unanimous
agreement of the provinces is required to amend it.
Third, no province can be allocated
fewer seats than it had in 1986; this is the grandfather clause, which protects
Newfoundland, Nova Scotia, Quebec, Manitoba and Saskatchewan, in addition to
providing additional protection to the two provinces protected by the
senatorial clause. This provision, unlike the preceding one, can be abolished
simply by an act of Parliament
The argument that the current
formula seriously undermines proportional representation failed the test of the
courts in 1987 88. The protection provided under the current formula to
provinces whose populations are decreasing may seem excessive compared to the
situation in typical federations such as the United States, Australia and
Switzerland. However, in those countries proportional representation was
accepted for the lower house only because states with very low populations were
considerably overrepresented in the upper house, whose powers were equal or
almost equal to those of the lower house.
This is not the case in Canada.
Historically, we have tended to make up for the lack of a powerful upper house
by providing provinces with low or decreasing populations more seats in the
House of Commons than their populations would justify. All the representation
formulas that have been used since 1867 have included provisions aimed at
either preventing a province from losing seats or minimizing any loss of seats.
Slowing the growth of the House of
Commons is not the least of the advantages of the current formula. It also
prevents each province from losing seats, which, in addition to fostering a
sense of security among seven provinces that account for 45% of the Canadian
population, minimizes the changes required after electoral redistribution and
addresses a very great concern of members, evidence of which can be found not
only in the 1970s but also throughout our entire electoral history.
Quebec does not fare too badly
under this formula, since the formula grants Quebec the protection accorded to
all the other provinces whose populations are increasing less quickly than the
average, and does so without favouring one province in particular, which the
25% clause in the Charlottetown Consensus Report would have done. Nothing
compels us to consider only Quebec s viewpoint on this issue, but this is one
aspect to take into account, like the views of the other regions of the
country.
The possibility of reducing the
size of the House of Commons has a number of implications which we should weigh
carefully. Here are three:
Virtually no riding would be left
intact by redistribution if the number of seats were reduced by 100 or even 50.
The result would be a boundary upheaval far greater than that for which MPs
criticized the 1993 commissions.
Reducing the number of seats would
mean increasing the average riding population. A House with 250 seats would
mean that the average riding population would increase from 91,500 to 108,000
(an 18% increase). For a House with 200 seats, the average would jump to
135,000, an increase of 48%. For members from rural or northern regions, this
would mean that the districts they represent would be even larger than they are
now. Because of this increased workload, additional riding staff would very
likely have to be hired. The advantages of a reduction in the number of seats
might be more symbolic than financial.
A major reduction in the total
number of seats would make the problem of provinces with declining populations
even more acute. Either the senatorial clause and the grandfather clause are
maintained in full, in which case the provinces with increasing populations
would complain about being penalized even more than they currently are; or this
protection is removed, in which case the provinces with declining populations
would likely greet this decision with hostility.